<SPAN name="toc9" id="toc9"></SPAN>
<SPAN name="pdf10" id="pdf10"></SPAN>
<h2><span>Preliminary Remarks.</span></h2>
<p>
Writers on Political Economy profess to teach, or to
investigate, the nature of Wealth, and the laws of its production
and distribution; including, directly or remotely, the
operation of all the causes by which the condition of mankind,
or of any society of human beings, in respect to this
universal object of human desire, is made prosperous or the
reverse.</p>
<span style="font-size: 90%">
It will be noticed that political economy does not include
ethics, legislation, or the science of government. The results
of political economy are offered to the statesman, who reaches
a conclusion after weighing them in connection with moral and
political considerations. Political Economy is distinct from
Sociology; although it is common to include in the former
everything which concerns social life. Some writers distinguish
between the pure, or abstract science, and the applied
art, and we can speak of a science of political economy only in
the sense of a body of abstract laws or formulas. This, however,
does not make political economy less practical than physics,
for, after a principle is ascertained, its operation is to be
observed in the same way that we study the force of gravitation
in a falling stone, even when retarded by opposing forces.
An economic force, or tendency, can be likewise distinctly observed,
although other influences, working at the same time,
prevent the expected effect from following its cause. It is, in
short, the aim of political economy to investigate the laws
which govern the phenomena of material wealth. (Cf. Cossa,
</span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">Guide,</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> chap. iii.)
</span>
<p>
While the [Mercantile] system prevailed, it was assumed,
either expressly or tacitly, in the whole policy of nations,
that wealth consisted solely of money; or of the precious
metals, which, when not already in the state of money, are
capable of being directly converted into it. According to
the doctrines then prevalent, whatever tended to heap up
money or bullion in a country added to its wealth.</p>
<span style="font-size: 90%">
More correctly the Mercantilists (in the sixteenth and seventeenth
centuries) held that where money was most plentiful,
there would be found the greatest abundance of the necessaries
of life.</span><SPAN id="noteref_100" name="noteref_100" href="#note_100"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">100</span></span></SPAN>
<p>
Whatever sent the precious metals out of a country impoverished
it. If a country possessed no gold or silver
mines, the only industry by which it could be enriched was
foreign trade, being the only one which could bring in
money. Any branch of trade which was supposed to send
out more money than it brought in, however ample and
valuable might be the returns in another shape, was looked
upon as a losing trade. Exportation of goods was favored
and encouraged (even by means extremely onerous to the
real resources of the country), because, the exported goods
being stipulated to be paid for in money, it was hoped that
the returns would actually be made in gold and silver. Importation
of anything, other than the precious metals, was
regarded as a loss to the nation of the whole price of the
things imported; unless they were brought in to be re-exported
at a profit, or unless, being the materials or instruments
of some industry practiced in the country itself, they
gave the power of producing exportable articles at smaller
cost, and thereby effecting a larger exportation. The commerce
of the world was looked upon as a struggle among
nations, which could draw to itself the largest share of the
gold and silver in existence; and in this competition no
nation could gain anything, except by making others lose
as much, or, at the least, preventing them from gaining it.</p>
<p>
The Mercantile Theory could not fail to be seen in its
true character when men began, even in an imperfect manner,
to explore into the foundations of things. Money, as
money, satisfies no want; its worth to any one consists in
its being a convenient shape in which to receive his incomings
of all sorts, which incomings he afterwards, at the times
which suit him best, converts into the forms in which they
can be useful to him. The difference between a country
with money, and a country altogether without it, would be
only one of convenience; a saving of time and trouble, like
grinding by water instead of by hand, or (to use Adam
Smith's illustration) like the benefit derived from roads;
and to mistake money for wealth is the same sort of error
as to mistake the highway, which may be the easiest way of
getting to your house or lands, for the house and lands themselves.</p>
<p>
Money, being the instrument of an important public and
private purpose, is rightly regarded as wealth; but everything
else which serves any human purpose, and which
nature does not afford gratuitously, is wealth also. To be
wealthy is to have a large stock of useful articles, or the
means of purchasing them. Everything forms, therefore, a
part of wealth, which has a power of purchasing; for which
anything useful or agreeable would be given in exchange.
Things for which nothing could be obtained in exchange,
however useful or necessary they may be, are not wealth in
the sense in which the term is used in Political Economy.
Air, for example, though the most absolute of necessaries,
bears no price in the market, because it can be obtained
gratuitously; to accumulate a stock of it would yield no
profit or advantage to any one; and the laws of its production
and distribution are the subject of a very different study
from Political Economy. It is possible to imagine circumstances
in which air would be a part of wealth. If it became
customary to sojourn long in places where the air does not
naturally penetrate, as in diving-bells sunk in the sea, a supply
of air artificially furnished would, like water conveyed
into houses, bear a price: and, if from any revolution in
nature the atmosphere became too scanty for the consumption,
or could be monopolized, air might acquire a very high
marketable value. In such a case, the possession of it, beyond
his own wants, would be, to its owner, wealth; and the
general wealth of mankind might at first sight appear to be
increased, by what would be so great a calamity to them.
The error would lie in not considering that, however rich
the possessor of air might become at the expense of the rest
of the community, all persons else would be poorer by all
that they were compelled to pay for what they had before
obtained without payment.</p>
<p>
Wealth, then, may be defined, all useful or agreeable
things which possess exchangeable value; or, in other
words, all useful or agreeable things except those which can
be obtained, in the quantity desired, without labor or sacrifice.</p>
<span style="font-size: 90%">
This is the usual definition of wealth. Henry George (see
</span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">Progress and Poverty,</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> pp. 34-37) regards wealth as consisting
</span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">of natural products that have been secured, moved, combined,
separated, or in other ways </span><em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">modified by human exertion</span></em><span style="font-size: 90%">,
so as to fit them for the gratification of human desires....
Nothing which Nature supplies to man without his labor is
wealth.... All things which have an exchange value are,
therefore, not wealth. Only such things can be wealth the
production of which increases and the destruction of which
decreases the aggregate of wealth.... Increase in land values
does not represent increase in the common wealth, for what
land-owners gain by higher prices the tenants or purchasers who
must pay them will lose.</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> Jevons (</span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">Primer,</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> p. 13) defines
wealth very properly as what is transferable, limited in supply,
and useful. F. A. Walker defines wealth as comprising </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">all
articles of value and nothing else</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> (</span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">Political Economy,</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> p. 5).
Levasseur's definition (</span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">Précis,</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> p. 15) is, </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">all material objects
possessing utility</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> (i.e., the power to satisfy a want). (Cf.
various definitions in Roscher's </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">Political Economy,</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> section
9, note 3.) Perry (</span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">Political Economy,</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> p. 99) rejects the term
</span><em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">wealth</span></em><span style="font-size: 90%"> as a clog to progress in
the science, and adopts </span><em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">property</span></em><span style="font-size: 90%">
in its stead, defining it as that </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">which can be bought or sold.</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%">
Cherbuliez (</span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">Précis,</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> p. 70) defines wealth as the material
product of nature appropriated by labor for the wants of man.
Carey (</span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">Social Science,</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> i, 186) asserts that wealth consists in
the power to command Nature's services, including in wealth
such intangible things as mental qualities.
</span>
<!--book-->
<div style="break-after:column;"></div><br />