<SPAN name="toc141" id="toc141"></SPAN>
<SPAN name="pdf142" id="pdf142"></SPAN>
<SPAN name="Book_III_Chapter_IV" id="Book_III_Chapter_IV" class="tei tei-anchor"></SPAN>
<h2><span>Chapter IV. Of Money.</span></h2>
<SPAN name="toc143" id="toc143"></SPAN>
<h3><span>§ 1. The three functions of Money—a Common Denominator of Value, a Medium of Exchange, a </span><span class="tei tei-q" style="text-align: left"><span style="font-size: 120%">“</span><span style="font-size: 120%">Standard of Value</span><span style="font-size: 120%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 120%">.</span></h3>
<p>
Having proceeded thus far in ascertaining the general
laws of Value, without introducing the idea of Money
(except occasionally for illustration), it is time that we should
now superadd that idea, and consider in what manner the
principles of the mutual interchange of commodities are
affected by the use of what is termed a Medium of Exchange.</p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
As Professor Jevons</span><SPAN id="noteref_220" name="noteref_220" href="#note_220"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">220</span></span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%"> has pointed out, money performs three
distinct services, capable of being separated by the mind, and
worthy of separate definition and explanation:
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
1. A Common Measure, or Common Denominator, of Value.
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
2. A Medium of Exchange.
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
3. A Standard of Value.
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
F. A. Walker,</span><SPAN id="noteref_221" name="noteref_221" href="#note_221"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">221</span></span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%"> however, says: </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">Money is the medium of
exchange. Whatever performs this function, does this work,
is money, no matter what it is made of.... That which does
the money-work is the money-thing.</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span></p>
<p>
(1.) [If we had no money] the first and most obvious [inconvenience]
would be the want of a <em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-style: italic">common measure for
values</span></em> of different sorts. If a tailor had only coats, and
wanted to buy bread or a horse, it would be very troublesome
to ascertain how much bread he ought to obtain for a coat,
or how many coats he should give for a horse. The calculation
must be recommenced on different data every time he
bartered his coats for a different kind of article, and there
could be no current price or regular quotations of value. As
it is much easier to compare different lengths by expressing
them in a common language of feet and inches, so it is much
easier to compare values by means of a common language of
[dollars and cents].</p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
The need of a common denominator of values (an excellent
term, introduced by Storch), to whose terms the values of all
other commodities may be reduced, and so compared, is as
great as that the inhabitants of the different States of the
United States should have a common language as a means by
which ideas could be communicated to the whole nation. A
man may have a horse, whose value he wishes to compare in
some common term with the value of his house, although he
might not wish to sell either. A valuation by the State for
taxation could not exist but for this common denominator, or
register, of value.
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
(2.) The second function is that of a medium of exchange.
The distinction between this function and the common denominator
of value is that the latter measures value, the former
transfers value. The man owning the horse, after having measured
its value by comparison with a given thing, may now wish
to exchange it for other things. This discloses the need of another
quality in money.
</span></p>
<p>
The inconveniences of barter are so great that, without
some more commodious means of effecting exchanges, the
division of employments could hardly have been carried to
any considerable extent. A tailor, who had nothing but
coats, might starve before he could find any person having
bread to sell who wanted a coat: besides, he would not want
as much bread at a time as would be worth a coat, and the
coat could not be divided. Every person, therefore, would
at all times hasten to dispose of his commodity in exchange
for anything which, though it might not be fitted to his own
immediate wants, was in great and general demand, and
easily divisible, so that he might be sure of being able to
purchase with it whatever was offered for sale. The thing
which people would select to keep by them for making purchases
must be one which, besides being divisible and generally
desired, does not deteriorate by keeping. This reduces
the choice to a small number of articles.</p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
This need is well explained by the following facts furnished
by Professor Jevons: </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">Some years since, Mademoiselle Zélie,
</span><span style="font-size: 90%">
a singer of the Théâtre Lyrique at Paris, made a professional
tour round the world, and gave a concert in the Society Islands.
In exchange for an air from </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">‘</span><span style="font-size: 90%">Norma</span><span style="font-size: 90%">’</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> and a few other songs,
she was to receive a third part of the receipts. When counted,
her share was found to consist of three pigs, twenty-three turkeys,
forty-four chickens, five thousand cocoanuts, besides considerable
quantities of bananas, lemons, and oranges. In the
Society Islands, however, pieces of money were very scarce;
and, as mademoiselle could not consume any considerable portion
of the receipts herself, it became necessary in the mean
time to feed the pigs and poultry with the fruit.</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><SPAN id="noteref_222" name="noteref_222" href="#note_222"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">222</span></span></SPAN></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
(3.) The third function desired of money is what is usually
termed a </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">standard of value.</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> It is, perhaps, better expressed
by F. A. Walker</span><SPAN id="noteref_223" name="noteref_223" href="#note_223"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">223</span></span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%"> as a </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">standard of deferred payments.</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> Its
existence is due to the desire to have a means of comparing the
purchasing power of a commodity at one time with its purchasing
power at another distant time; that is, that for long contracts,
exchanges may be in unchanged ratios at the beginning
and at the end of the contracts. There is no distinction between
this function and the first, except one arising from the
introduction of </span><em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">time</span></em><span style="font-size: 90%">. At the same time and place, the </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">standard
of value</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> is given in the common denominator of value.
</span></p>
<p>
A Measure of Value,<SPAN id="noteref_224" name="noteref_224" href="#note_224"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">224</span></span></SPAN>
in the ordinary sense of the word
measure, would mean something by comparison with which
we may ascertain what is the value of any other thing.
When we consider, further, that value itself is relative, and
that two things are necessary to constitute it, independently
of the third thing which is to measure it, we may define a
Measure of Value to be something, by comparing with which
any two other things, we may infer their value in relation
to one another.</p>
<p>
In this sense, any commodity will serve as a measure of
value at a given time and place; since we can always infer
the proportion in which things exchange for one another,
when we know the proportion in which each exchanges for
any third thing. To serve as a convenient measure of value
is one of the functions of the commodity selected as a medium
of exchange. It is in that commodity that the values
of all other things are habitually estimated.</p>
<p>
But the desideratum sought by political economists is
not a measure of the value of things at the same time and
place, but a measure of the value of the same thing at different
times and places: something by comparison with
which it may be known whether any given thing is of
greater or less value now than a century ago, or in this
country than in America or China. To enable the money
price of a thing at two different periods to measure the
quantity of things in general which it will exchange for, the
same sum of money must correspond at both periods to the
same quantity of things in general—that is, money must
always have the same exchange value, the same general purchasing
power. Now, not only is this not true of money, or
of any other commodity, but we can not even suppose any
state of circumstances in which it would be true.</p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
It being very clear that money, or the precious metals, do
not themselves remain absolutely stable in value for long periods,
the only way in which a </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">standard of value</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> can be properly
established is by the proposed </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">multiple standard of
value,</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> stated as follows:
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em">
<span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">A number of articles in general use—corn, beef, potatoes,
wool, cotton, silk, tea, sugar, coffee, indigo, timber, iron, coal,
and others—shall be taken, in a definite quantity of each, so
many pounds, or bushels, or cords, or yards, to form a standard
required. The value of these articles, in the quantities specified,
and all of standard quality, shall be ascertained monthly
or weekly by Government, and the total sum [in money] which
would then purchase this bill of goods shall be, thereupon,
officially promulgated. Persons may then, if they choose, make
their contracts for future payments in terms of this multiple
or tabular standard.</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><SPAN id="noteref_225" name="noteref_225" href="#note_225"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">225</span></span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%">
A, who had borrowed $1,000 of B in
1870 for ten years, would make note of the total money value
of all these articles composing the multiple standard, which we
will suppose is $125 in 1870. Consequently, A would promise
to pay B eight multiple units in ten years (that is, eight times
$125, or $1,000). But, if other things change in value relatively
</span><span style="font-size: 90%">
to money during these ten years, the same sum of money—$1,000—in
1880 will not return to B the same just amount
of purchasing power which he parted with in 1870. Now, if,
in 1880, when his note falls due, the government list is examined,
and it is found that commodities in general have fallen in
value relatively to gold, the multiple unit will not amount to
as much gold as it did in 1870; perhaps each unit may be
rated only at $100. In that case, A is obliged to pay back but
eight multiple units, which costs him only $800 in money, while
B receives from A the same amount of purchasing power over
other commodities which he loaned to him. B had no just claim
to ten units, since the fall of all commodities relatively to gold
was not due to his exertions. On the other hand, if, between
1870 and 1880, prices had risen, </span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">mutatis mutandis</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%">, the eight
units would have cost A more than $1,000 in gold; but he would
have been justly obliged to return the same amount of purchasing
power to B which he received from him.
</span></p>
<SPAN name="toc144" id="toc144"></SPAN>
<h3><span>§ 2. Gold and Silver, why fitted for those purposes.</span></h3>
<p>
By a tacit concurrence, almost all nations, at a very
early period, fixed upon certain metals, and especially gold
and silver, to serve this purpose. No other substances unite
the necessary qualities in so great a degree, with so many
subordinate advantages. These were the things which it
most pleased every one to possess, and which there was most
certainty of finding others willing to receive in exchange
for any kind of produce. They were among the most imperishable
of all substances. They were also portable, and,
containing great value in small bulk, were easily hid; a consideration
of much importance in an age of insecurity.
Jewels are inferior to gold and silver in the quality of
divisibility; and are of very various qualities, not to be accurately
discriminated without great trouble. Gold and silver
are eminently divisible, and, when pure, always of the
same quality; and their purity may be ascertained and certified
by a public authority.</p>
<p>
Jevons<SPAN id="noteref_226" name="noteref_226" href="#note_226"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">226</span></span></SPAN> has more fully stated the requisites for a perfect
money as—</p>
<table summary="This is a list." class="tei tei-list" style="margin-bottom: 1.00em; margin-top: 1.00em"><tbody><tr class="tei tei-labelitem"><th class="tei tei-label"></th><td class="tei tei-item">1. Value.</td></tr><tr class="tei tei-labelitem"><th class="tei tei-label"></th><td class="tei tei-item">2. Portability.</td></tr><tr class="tei tei-labelitem"><th class="tei tei-label"></th><td class="tei tei-item">3. Indestructibility.</td></tr><tr class="tei tei-labelitem"><th class="tei tei-label"></th><td class="tei tei-item">4. Homogeneity.</td></tr><tr class="tei tei-labelitem"><th class="tei tei-label"></th><td class="tei tei-item">5. Divisibility.</td></tr><tr class="tei tei-labelitem"><th class="tei tei-label"></th><td class="tei tei-item">6. Stability of value.</td></tr><tr class="tei tei-labelitem"><th class="tei tei-label"></th><td class="tei tei-item">7. Cognizability.</td></tr></tbody></table>
<p>
Accordingly, though furs have been employed as money
in some countries, cattle in others, in Chinese Tartary cubes
of tea closely pressed together, the shells called cowries on
the coast of Western Africa, and in Abyssinia at this day
blocks of rock-salt, gold and silver have been generally preferred
by nations which were able to obtain them, either by
industry, commerce, or conquest. To the qualities which
originally recommended them, another came to be added,
the importance of which only unfolded itself by degrees.
Of all commodities, they are among the least influenced by
any of the causes which produce fluctuations of value. No
commodity is quite free from such fluctuations. Gold and
silver have sustained, since the beginning of history, one
great permanent alteration of value, from the discovery of
the American mines.</p>
<p>
In the present age the opening of new sources of supply,
so abundant as the Ural Mountains, California, and Australia,
may be the commencement of another period of decline, on
the limits of which it would be useless at present to speculate.
But, on the whole, no commodities are so little exposed
to causes of variation. They fluctuate less than almost
any other things in their cost of production. And, from
their durability, the total quantity in existence is at all times
so great in proportion to the annual supply, that the effect
on value even of a change in the cost of production is not
sudden: a very long time being required to diminish materially
the quantity in existence, and even to increase it very
greatly not being a rapid process. Gold and silver, therefore,
are more fit than any other commodity to be the subject
of engagements for receiving or paying a given quantity
at some distant period.</p>
<span style="font-size: 90%">
Since Mr. Mill wrote, two great changes in the production
of the precious metals have occurred. The discoveries of gold,
briefly referred to by him, have led to an enormous increase of
the existing fund of gold (see chart </span><SPAN href="#Chart_IX" class="tei tei-ref"><span style="font-size: 90%">No. IX</span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%">,
</span><SPAN href="#Book_III_Chapter_VI" class="tei tei-ref"><span style="font-size: 90%">Chap. VI</span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%">), and a
fall in the value of gold within twenty years after the discoveries,
according to Mr. Jevons's celebrated study,</span><SPAN id="noteref_227" name="noteref_227" href="#note_227"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">227</span></span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%"> of from nine
</span><span style="font-size: 90%">
to fifteen per cent. Another change took place, a change in
the value, of silver, in 1876, which has resulted in a permanent
fall of its value since that time (see chart </span><SPAN href="#Chart_X" class="tei tei-ref"><span style="font-size: 90%">No. X</span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%">,
</span><SPAN href="#Book_III_Chapter_VII" class="tei tei-ref"><span style="font-size: 90%">Chap. VII</span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%">).
Before that date, silver sold at about 60</span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">d.</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%">
per ounce in the central market of the world, London; and now it remains about
52</span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">d.</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> per ounce, although it once fell to
47</span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">d.</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%">, in July, 1876. In
spite of Mr. Mill's expressions of confidence in their stability of
value—although certainly more stable than other commodities—the
events of the last thirty-five years have fully shown that
neither gold nor silver—silver far less than gold—can successfully
serve as a perfect </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">standard of value</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> for any considerable
length of time.
</span>
<p>
When gold and silver had become virtually a medium
of exchange, by becoming the things for which people generally
sold, and with which they generally bought, whatever
they had to sell or to buy, the contrivance of coining obviously
suggested itself. By this process the metal was
divided into convenient portions, of any degree of smallness,
and bearing a recognized proportion to one another; and the
trouble was saved of weighing and assaying at every change
of possessors—an inconvenience which, on the occasion of
small purchases, would soon have become insupportable.
Governments found it their interest to take the operation
into their own hands, and to interdict all coining by private
persons.</p>
<SPAN name="toc145" id="toc145"></SPAN>
<h3><span>§ 3. Money a mere contrivance for facilitating exchanges, which does not affect the laws of value.</span></h3>
<p>
It must be evident, however, that the mere introduction
of a particular mode of exchanging things for one
another, by first exchanging a thing for money, and then exchanging
the money for something else, makes no difference
in the essential character of transactions. It is not with
money that things are really purchased. Nobody's income
(except that of the gold or silver miner) is derived from the
precious metals. The [dollars or cents] which a person receives
weekly or yearly are not what constitutes his income;
they are a sort of tickets or orders which he can present for
payment at any shop he pleases, and which entitle him to receive
a certain value of any commodity that he makes choice
of. The farmer pays his laborers and his landlord in these
tickets, as the most convenient plan for himself and them;
but their real income is their share of his corn, cattle, and
hay, and it makes no essential difference whether he distributes
it to them directly, or sells it for them and gives
them the price. There can not, in short, be intrinsically a
more insignificant thing, in the economy of society, than
money; except in the character of a contrivance for sparing
time and labor. It is a machine for doing quickly and commodiously
what would be done, though less quickly and
commodiously, without it; and, like many other kinds of
machinery, it only exerts a distinct and independent influence
of its own when it gets out of order.</p>
<p>
The introduction of money does not interfere with the
operation of any of the Laws of Value laid down in the preceding
chapters. The reasons which make the temporary or
market value of things depend on the demand and supply,
and their average and permanent values upon their cost of
production, are as applicable to a money system as to a system
of barter. Things which by barter would exchange for
one another will, if sold for money, sell for an equal amount
of it, and so will exchange for one another still, though the
process of exchanging them will consist of two operations
instead of only one. The relations of commodities to one
another remain unaltered by money; the only new relation
introduced is their relation to money itself; how much or
how little money they will exchange for; in other words,
how the Exchange Value of money itself is determined.
Money is a commodity, and its value is determined like that
of other commodities, temporarily by demand and supply,
permanently and on the average by cost of production.</p>
<hr class="page" />
<div style="break-after:column;"></div><br />