<SPAN name="toc146" id="toc146"></SPAN>
<SPAN name="pdf147" id="pdf147"></SPAN>
<SPAN name="Book_III_Chapter_V" id="Book_III_Chapter_V" class="tei tei-anchor"></SPAN>
<h2><span>Chapter V. Of The Value Of Money, As Dependent On Demand And Supply.</span></h2>
<SPAN name="toc148" id="toc148"></SPAN>
<h3><span>§ 1. Value of Money, an ambiguous expression.</span></h3>
<p>
The Value of Money is to appearance an expression as
precise, as free from possibility of misunderstanding, as any
in science. The value of a thing is what it will exchange
for; the value of money is what money will exchange for,
the purchasing power of money. If prices are low, money
will buy much of other things, and is of high value; if prices
are high, it will buy little of other things, and is of low
value. The value of money is inversely as general prices;
falling as they rise, and rising as they fall. When one person
lends to another, as well as when he pays wages or rent
to another, what he transfers is not the mere money, but a
right to a certain value of the produce of the country, to be
selected at pleasure; the lender having first bought this
right, by giving for it a portion of his capital. What he
really lends is so much capital; the money is the mere instrument
of transfer. But the capital usually passes from the
lender to the receiver through the means either of money, or
of an order to receive money, and at any rate it is in money
that the capital is computed and estimated. Hence, borrowing
capital is universally called borrowing money; the loan
market is called the money market; those who have their
capital disposable for investment on loan are called the moneyed
class; and the equivalent given for the use of capital,
or, in other words, interest, is not only called the interest of
money, but, by a grosser perversion of terms, the value of
money.</p>
<SPAN name="toc149" id="toc149"></SPAN>
<h3><span>§ 2. The Value of Money depends on its quantity.</span></h3>
<p>
The value or purchasing power of money depends,
in the first instance, on demand and supply. But demand
and supply, in relation to money, present themselves in a
somewhat different shape from the demand and supply of
other things.</p>
<p>
The supply of a commodity means the quantity offered
for sale. But it is not usual to speak of offering money for
sale. People are not usually said to buy or sell money.
This, however, is merely an accident of language. In point
of fact, money is bought and sold like other things, whenever
other things are bought and sold <em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-style: italic">for</span></em> money. Whoever sells
corn, or tallow, or cotton, buys money. Whoever buys bread,
or wine, or clothes, sells money to the dealer in those articles.
The money with which people are offering to buy, is money
offered for sale. The supply of money, then, is the quantity
of it which people are wanting to lay out; that is, all the
money they have in their possession, except what they are
hoarding, or at least keeping by them as a reserve for future
contingencies. The supply of money, in short, is all the
money in <em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-style: italic">circulation</span></em> at the time.</p>
<p>
The demand for money, again, consists of all the goods
offered for sale. Every seller of goods is a buyer of money,
and the goods he brings with him constitute his demand.
The demand for money differs from the demand for other
things in this, that it is limited only by the means of the
purchaser.</p>
<span style="font-size: 90%">
In this last statement Mr. Mill is misled by his former definition
of demand as </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">quantity demanded.</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> He has the true idea
of demand in this case regarding money; but the demand for
money does not, as he thinks, differ from the demand for other
things, inasmuch as, in our corrected view of demand for other
things (p. </span><SPAN href="#Pg255" class="tei tei-ref"><span style="font-size: 90%">255</span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%">), it was found that the demand for other things
than money was also limited by the means of the purchaser.</span><SPAN id="noteref_228" name="noteref_228" href="#note_228"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">228</span></span></SPAN>
<p>
As the whole of the goods in the market compose the
demand for money, so the whole of the money constitutes
the demand for goods. The money and the goods are seeking
each other for the purpose of being exchanged. They
are reciprocally supply and demand to one another. It is
indifferent whether, in characterizing the phenomena, we
speak of the demand and supply of goods, or the supply and
the demand of money. They are equivalent expressions.</p>
<p>
Supposing the money in the hands of individuals to be
increased, the wants and inclinations of the community collectively
in respect to consumption remaining exactly the
same, the increase of demand would reach all things equally,
and there would be a universal rise of prices. Let us rather
suppose, therefore, that to every pound, or shilling, or penny
in the possession of any one, another pound, shilling, or
penny were suddenly added. There would be an increased
money demand, and consequently an increased money value,
or price, for things of all sorts. This increased value would
do no good to any one; would make no difference, except
that of having to reckon [dollars and cents] in higher numbers.
It would be an increase of values only as estimated in
money, a thing only wanted to buy other things with; and
would not enable any one to buy more of them than before.
Prices would have risen in a certain ratio, and the value of
money would have fallen in the same ratio.</p>
<p>
It is to be remarked that this ratio would be precisely
that in which the quantity of money had been increased. If
the whole money in circulation was doubled, prices would be
doubled. If it was only increased one fourth, prices would
rise one fourth. There would be one fourth more money, all
of which would be used to purchase goods of some description.
When there had been time for the increased supply
of money to reach all markets, or (according to the conventional
metaphor) to permeate all the channels of circulation,
all prices would have risen one fourth. But the general rise
of price is independent of this diffusing and equalizing process.
Even if some prices were raised more, and others less,
the average rise would be one fourth. This is a necessary
consequence of the fact that a fourth more money would
have been given for only the same quantity of goods. <em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-style: italic">General</span></em>
prices, therefore, would in any case be a fourth higher.</p>
<p>
So that the value of money, other things being the same,
varies inversely as its quantity; every increase of quantity
lowering the value, and every diminution raising it, in a ratio
exactly equivalent. This, it must be observed, is a property
peculiar to money. We did not find it to be true of commodities
generally, that every diminution of supply raised
the value exactly in proportion to the deficiency, or that
every increase lowered it in the precise ratio of the excess.
Some things are usually affected in a greater ratio than that
of the excess or deficiency, others usually in a less; because,
in ordinary cases of demand, the desire, being for the thing
itself, may be stronger or weaker; and the amount of what
people are willing to expend on it, being in any case a limited
quantity, may be affected in very unequal degrees by
difficulty or facility of attainment. But in the case of
money, which is desired as the means of universal purchase,
the demand consists of everything which people have to sell;
and the only limit to what they are willing to give, is the
limit set by their having nothing more to offer. The whole
of the goods being in any case exchanged for the whole of
the money which comes into the market to be laid out, they
will sell for less or more of it, exactly according as less or
more is brought.</p>
<SPAN name="toc150" id="toc150"></SPAN>
<h3><span>§ 3. —Together with the Rapidity of Circulation.</span></h3>
<p>
It might be supposed that there is always in circulation
in a country a quantity of money equal in value to the
whole of the goods then and there on sale. But this would
be a complete misapprehension. The money laid out is
equal in value to the goods it purchases; but the quantity of
money laid out is not the same thing with the quantity in
circulation. As the money passes from hand to hand, the
same piece of money is laid out many times before all the
things on sale at one time are purchased and finally removed
from the market; and each pound or dollar must be counted
for as many pounds or dollars as the number of times it
changes hands in order to effect this object.</p>
<p>
If we assume the quantity of goods on sale, and the number
of times those goods are resold, to be fixed quantities, the
value of money will depend upon its quantity, together with
the average number of times that each piece changes hands
in the process. The whole of the goods sold (counting each
resale of the same goods as so much added to the goods) have
been exchanged for the whole of the money, multiplied by
the number of purchases made on the average by each piece.
Consequently, the amount of goods and of transactions being
the same, the value of money is inversely as its quantity
multiplied by what is called the rapidity of circulation. And
the quantity of money in circulation is equal to the money
value of all the goods sold, divided by the number which
expresses the rapidity of circulation.</p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
This may be expressed in mathematical language, where V
is the value of money, Q is the quantity in circulation, and R
the number expressing the rapidity of circulation, as follows:
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
V = 1 / (Q × R).
</span></p>
<p>
The phrase, rapidity of circulation, requires some comment.
It must not be understood to mean the number of
purchases made by each piece of money in a given time.
Time is not the thing to be considered. The state of society
may be such that each piece of money hardly performs more
than one purchase in a year; but if this arises from the
small number of transactions—from the small amount of
business done, the want of activity in traffic, or because
what traffic there is mostly takes place by barter—it constitutes
no reason why prices should be lower, or the value of
money higher. The essential point is, not how often the
same money changes hands in a given time, but how often
it changes hands in order to perform a given amount of
traffic. We must compare the number of purchases made
by the money in a given time, not with the time itself, but
with the goods sold in that same time. If each piece of
money changes hands on an average ten times while goods
are sold to the value of a million sterling, it is evident that
the money required to circulate those goods is £100,000.
And, conversely, if the money in circulation is £100,000, and
each piece changes hands, by the purchase of goods, ten times
in a month, the sales of goods for money which take place
every month must amount, on the average, to £1,000,000.
[The essential point to be considered is] the average number
of purchases made by each piece in order to affect a given
pecuniary amount of transactions.</p>
<span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">There is no doubt that the rapidity of circulation varies
very much between one country and another. A thrifty people
with slight banking facilities, like the French, Swiss, Belgians,
and Dutch, hoard coin much more than an improvident
people like the English, or even a careful people, with a perfect
banking system, like the Scotch. Many circumstances,
too, affect the rapidity of circulation. Railways and rapid
steamboats enable coin and bullion to be more swiftly remitted
than of old; telegraphs prevent its needless removal, and the
acceleration of the mails has a like effect.</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span> <span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">So different are
the commercial habits of different peoples, that there evidently
exists no proportion whatever between the amount of currency
in a country and the aggregate of the exchanges which can be
effected by it.</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><SPAN id="noteref_229" name="noteref_229" href="#note_229"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">229</span></span></SPAN>
<SPAN name="toc151" id="toc151"></SPAN>
<h3><span>§ 4. Explanations and Limitations of this Principle.</span></h3>
<p>
The proposition which we have laid down respecting
the dependence of general prices upon the quantity of money
in circulation must be understood as applying only to a state
of things in which money—that is, gold or silver—is the exclusive
instrument of exchange, and actually passes from
hand to hand at every purchase, credit in any of its shapes
being unknown. When credit comes into play as a means
of purchasing, distinct from money in hand, we shall hereafter
find that the connection between prices and the amount
of the circulating medium is much less direct and intimate,
and that such connection as does exist no longer admits of
so simple a mode of expression. That an increase of the
quantity of money raises prices, and a diminution lowers
them, is the most elementary proposition in the theory of
currency, and without it we should have no key to any of
the others. In any state of things, however, except the
simple and primitive one which we have supposed, the
proposition is only true, other things being the same.</p>
<p>
It is habitually assumed that whenever there is a greater
amount of money in the country, or in existence, a rise of
prices must necessarily follow. But this is by no means an
inevitable consequence. In no commodity is it the quantity
in existence, but the quantity offered for sale, that determines
the value. Whatever may be the quantity of money
in the country, only that part of it will affect prices which
goes into the market of commodities, and is there actually
exchanged against goods. Whatever increases the amount
of this portion of the money in the country tends to raise
prices.</p>
<span style="font-size: 90%">
This statement needs modification, since the change in the
amounts of specie in the bank reserves, particularly of England
and the United States, determines the amount of credit
and purchasing power granted, and so affects prices in that
way; but prices are affected not by this specie being actually
exchanged against goods.
</span>
<p>
It frequently happens that money to a considerable
amount is brought into the country, is there actually invested
as capital, and again flows out, without having ever
once acted upon the markets of commodities, but only upon
the market of securities, or, as it is commonly though improperly
called, the money market.</p>
<p>
A foreigner landing in the country with a treasure might
very probably prefer to invest his fortune at interest; which
we shall suppose him to do in the most obvious way by becoming
a competitor for a portion of the stock, railway debentures,
mercantile bills, mortgages, etc., which are at all
times in the hands of the public. By doing this he would
raise the prices of those different securities, or in other
words would lower the rate of interest; and since this
would disturb the relation previously existing between the
rate of interest on capital in the country itself and that in
foreign countries, it would probably induce some of those
who had floating capital seeking employment to send it
abroad for foreign investment, rather than buy securities at
home at the advanced price. As much money might thus
go out as had previously come in, while the prices of commodities
would have shown no trace of its temporary presence.
This is a case highly deserving of attention; and it is
a fact now beginning to be recognized that the passage of
the precious metals from country to country is determined
much more than was formerly supposed by the state of the
loan market in different countries, and much less by the state
of prices.</p>
<p>
If there be, at any time, an increase in the number of
money transactions, a thing continually liable to happen
from differences in the activity of speculation, and even in
the time of year (since certain kinds of business are transacted
only at particular seasons), an increase of the currency
which is only proportional to this increase of transactions,
and is of no longer duration, has no tendency to raise prices.</p>
<span style="font-size: 90%">
For example, bankers in Eastern cities each year send in
the autumn to the West, as the crops are gathered, very large
sums of money, to settle transactions in the buying and selling
of grain, wool, etc., but it again flows back to the great centers
of business in a short time, in payment of purchases from
Eastern merchants.
</span>
<hr class="page" />
<div style="break-after:column;"></div><br />