<SPAN name="toc178" id="toc178"></SPAN>
<SPAN name="pdf179" id="pdf179"></SPAN>
<SPAN name="Book_III_Chapter_X" id="Book_III_Chapter_X" class="tei tei-anchor"></SPAN>
<h2><span>Chapter X. Of An Inconvertible Paper Currency.</span></h2>
<SPAN name="toc180" id="toc180"></SPAN>
<h3><span>§ 1. What determines the value of an inconvertible paper money?</span></h3>
<p>
After experience had shown that pieces of paper, of
no intrinsic value, by merely bearing upon them the written
profession of being equivalent to a certain number of francs,
dollars, or pounds, could be made to circulate as such, and
to produce all the benefit to the issuers which could have
been produced by the coins which they purported to represent,
governments began to think that it would be a happy
device if they could appropriate to themselves this benefit,
free from the condition to which individuals issuing such
paper substitutes for money were subject, of giving, when
required, for the sign, the thing signified. They determined
to try whether they could not emancipate themselves
from this unpleasant obligation, and make a piece of
paper issued by them pass for a pound, by merely calling
it a pound, and consenting to receive it in payment of the
taxes.</p>
<p>
In the case supposed, the functions of money are performed
by a thing which derives its power of performing
them solely from convention; but convention is quite sufficient
to confer the power; since nothing more is needful to
make a person accept anything as money, and even at any
arbitrary value, than the persuasion that it will be taken
from him on the same terms by others. The only question
is, what determines the value of such a currency, since it can
not be, as in the case of gold and silver (or paper exchangeable
for them at pleasure), the cost of production.</p>
<p>
We have seen, however, that even in the case of metallic
currency, the immediate agency in determining its value
is its quantity. If the quantity, instead of depending on
the ordinary mercantile motives of profit and loss, could be
arbitrarily fixed by authority, the value would depend on
the fiat of that authority, not on cost of production. The
quantity of a paper currency not convertible into the metals
at the option of the holder <em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-style: italic">can</span></em> be arbitrarily fixed,
especially if the issuer is the sovereign power of the
state. The value, therefore, of such a currency is entirely
arbitrary.</p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
The value of paper money is, of course, primarily and mainly
dependent on the quantity issued. The general level of
value depends on the </span><em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">quantity</span></em><span style="font-size: 90%">; but we also find that deviations
from this general level, in the direction of further depreciation
than could be due to quantity alone, is caused by any
event which shakes the confidence of any one that he may get
the existing value for his paper. The </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">convention</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> by which
real value (the essential idea of money) was associated with
this paper in the minds of all is thereby broken.
</span><em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">Fiat</span></em><span style="font-size: 90%"> money—that
is, a piece of paper, not containing a promise to pay a
dollar, but a simple declaration that this is a dollar—therefore,
separates the paper from any connection with value. And yet
we see that </span><em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">fiat</span></em><span style="font-size: 90%"> money has some, although a fluctuating, value
at certain times: if the State receives it for taxes, if it is a legal
acquittal of obligations, then, to that extent, a certain quantity
of it is given a value equal to the wealth represented by the
taxes, or the debts. Jevons remarks on this point</span><SPAN id="noteref_247" name="noteref_247" href="#note_247"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">247</span></span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%"> that, if
</span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">the quantity of notes issued was kept within such moderate
limits that any one wishing to realize the metallic value of the
notes could find some one wanting to pay taxes, and therefore
willing to give coin for notes,</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> stability of value might be secured.
If there is more in circulation than performs these functions,
it will depreciate in the proportion of the </span><em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">quantity</span></em><span style="font-size: 90%"> to the
extent of the uses assigned to it; so that the relation of quantity
to uses is the only thing which can give value to </span><em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">fiat</span></em><span style="font-size: 90%"> money,
but beyond a certain point in the issues other forces than mere
quantity begin to affect the value. Although the paper is not
even a promise to pay value, the form of expression on its face,
or the term used as its designation, generally tends, under the
force of convention and habit, to give a popular value to paper.
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
Although the State may not promise to pay a dollar, yet, wherever
such paper money carries any purchasing power with it
(which has very seldom happened, and then only for short periods),
it will be found that there is a vague popular understanding
that the State intends, at some time or other, to redeem the
notes with value in coin to some amount. In the early cases of
irredeemable money in our colonies, the income of taxes, or similar
resources, were promised as a means of redemption. To some—although
a slight—extent, the idea of value was associated
with such paper. The actual quantity issued did not measure
the depreciation. The paper did depreciate with increased issues.
But only in so far as the increased issues proved to the
community that there was less and less possibility of ever receiving
value for them did they depreciate. In other words, we come
to the familiar experience, known to many, of a paper money depending
for its value on the opinions of men in the country. This
was partially true, even of our own greenbacks, which were not
</span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">fiat</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> money, but promises to pay (although not then redeemable),
as may be seen by the movement of the line in </span><SPAN href="#Chart_XII" class="tei tei-ref"><span style="font-size: 90%">Chart XII</span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%">
(p. </span><SPAN href="#Pg359" class="tei tei-ref"><span style="font-size: 90%">359</span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%">), which represents
the fluctuations of our paper money during
the civil war. The upward movement of the line, which indicates
the premium on gold during our late war, of course represents
correspondingly the depreciation of the paper. Every
victory or defeat of the Union arms raised or lowered the premium
on gold; it was the register of the opinion of the people as to
the value to be associated with the paper. The second and third
resorts to issues of greenbacks were regarded as confessions of
financial distress; it was this which produced the effect on their
value. It was not only the quantity but also that which caused
the issue of the quantity. It is, of course, clear that the value of
a paper money like the greenbacks, which were the promises to
pay of a rich country, would bear a definite relation to the actual
quantity issued; and this is to be seen by the generally
higher level of the line on the chart, showing a steadily diminishing
purchasing power as the issues increased. But the thing
which weighed largely in people's minds was the possibility of
ultimate redemption; and the premium on gold was practically
a register of the </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">betting</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> on this possibility. In 1878, when
Secretary Sherman's reserve was seen to be increasing to an
effective amount, and when it became evident that he would
have the means (i.e., the value represented by all the paper
that was likely to be presented) to resume on the day set, January
1, 1879, the premium gradually faded away. The general
shifting of the level to a lower stage in this later period was
not due to any decrease in the quantity outstanding, because
the contraction had been stopped in 1868, and that consequent
on the resumption act in May, 1878.
</span></p>
<p>
Suppose that, in a country of which the currency is
wholly metallic, a paper currency is suddenly issued, to the
amount of half the metallic circulation; not by a banking
establishment, or in the form of loans, but by the Government,
in payment of salaries and purchase of commodities.
The currency being suddenly increased by one half, all prices
will rise, and, among the rest, the prices of all things made
of gold and silver. An ounce of manufactured gold will become
more valuable than an ounce of gold coin, by more
than that customary difference which compensates for the
value of the workmanship; and it will be profitable to melt
the coin for the purpose of being manufactured, until as
much has been taken from the currency by the subtraction
of gold as had been added to it by the issue of paper. Then
prices will relapse to what they were at first, and there will
be nothing changed, except that a paper currency has been
substituted for half of the metallic currency which existed
before. Suppose, now, a second emission of paper; the
same series of effects will be renewed; and so on, until the
whole of the metallic money has disappeared [see Chart
No. <SPAN href="#Chart_XIV" class="tei tei-ref">XIV</SPAN>,
<SPAN href="#Book_III_Chapter_XV" class="tei tei-ref">Chap. XV</SPAN>, for the exportation of gold from the
United States after the issue of our paper money in 1862]:
that is, if paper be issued of as low a denomination as
the lowest coin; if not, as much will remain as convenience
requires for the smaller payments. The addition
made to the quantity of gold and silver disposable for
ornamental purposes will somewhat reduce, for a time, the
value of the article; and as long as this is the case, even
though paper has been issued to the original amount of
the metallic circulation, as much coin will remain in circulation
along with it as will keep the value of the currency
down to the reduced value of the metallic material;
but the value having fallen below the cost of production, a
stoppage or diminution of the supply from the mines will
enable the surplus to be carried off by the ordinary agents of
destruction, after which the metals and the currency will
recover their natural value. We are here supposing, as we
have supposed throughout, that the country has mines of its
own, and no commercial intercourse with other countries;
for, in a country having foreign trade, the coin which is rendered
superfluous by an issue of paper is carried off by a
much prompter method.</p>
<span style="font-size: 90%">
Mr. Mill's statement, that, if paper be not issued of as low
a denomination as the lowest coin, </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">as much will remain as
convenience requires for the smaller payments,</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> will not hold
true. During our recent experiment of depreciated paper, the
depreciation was such as to drive out the subsidiary silver coins,
by July, 1862, and we were forced to supply their place by a
fractional paper currency. By an amendment inserted June 17,
1862, into the act authorizing a second issue of $150,000,000 of
greenbacks, it was ordered </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">that no note shall be issued for
the fractional part of a dollar, and not more than $35,000,000
shall be of lower denominations than five dollars</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> (act, finally
passed July 11, 1862). Although there were no fractional
notes, yet one-dollar notes drove out subsidiary silver, simply
because the paper had depreciated to a value below that of the
345.6 grains of silver in two halves or four quarters of a dollar.
By July 2d the disappearance of small coin was distinctly noted.
Let the value of gold be represented by 100; and a dollar of
small silver coin (345.6 grains), relatively to a gold dollar,
by 96. Now, if paper depreciates to 90, relatively to gold, it
will drive out the subsidiary silver at 96, in accordance with
Gresham's law.
</span>
<p>
Up to this point the effects of a paper currency are substantially
the same, whether it is convertible into specie or
not. It is when the metals have been completely superseded
and driven from circulation that the difference between
convertible and inconvertible paper begins to be operative.
When the gold or silver has all gone from circulation,
and an equal amount of paper has taken its place,
suppose that a still further issue is superadded. The same
series of phenomena recommences: prices rise, among the
rest the prices of gold and silver articles, and it becomes an
object, as before, to procure coin, in order to convert it into
bullion. There is no longer any coin in circulation; but, if
the paper currency is convertible, coin may still be obtained
from the issuers in exchange for notes. All additional notes,
therefore, which are attempted to be forced into circulation
after the metals have been completely superseded, will return
upon the issuers in exchange for coin; and they will not be
able to maintain in circulation such a quantity of convertible
paper as to sink its value below the metal which it represents.
It is not so, however, with an inconvertible currency.
To the increase of that (if permitted by law) there is no
check. The issuers may add to it indefinitely, lowering its
value and raising prices in proportion; they may, in other
words, depreciate the currency without limit.</p>
<p>
Such a power, in whomsoever vested, is an intolerable
evil. All variations in the value of the circulating medium
are mischievous: they disturb existing contracts and expectations,
and the liability to such changes renders every pecuniary
engagement of long date entirely precarious. The person
who buys for himself, or gives to another, an annuity
of one [hundred dollars], does not know whether it will be
equivalent to [two hundred or to fifty dollars] a few years
hence. Great as this evil would be if it depended only on
accident, it is still greater when placed at the arbitrary disposal
of an individual or a body of individuals, who may
have any kind or degree of interest to be served by an artificial
fluctuation in fortunes, and who have at any rate a
strong interest in issuing as much as possible, each issue
being in itself a source of profit—not to add, that the issuers
may have, and, in the case of a government paper, always
have, a direct interest in lowering the value of the
currency, because it is the medium in which their own debts
are computed.</p>
<span style="font-size: 90%">
The United States Supreme Court had decided in December,
1870, by the second legal-tender decision, that the issue of
greenbacks (inconvertible from 1862 to 1879) was constitutional
during a time of war; but it was thought that the reissue of
these notes since the war, when no war emergency could be
pleaded, was unconstitutional. This view, however, was met by
the unfortunate decision of the Supreme Court, delivered by
Justice Gray, March, 1884, which announced the doctrine that
the expediency of an issue of legal-tender paper money was to
be determined solely by Congress; and that, if Congress judged
the issue expedient, it was within the limits of those provisions
</span><span style="font-size: 90%">
of the Constitution (section 8), which gave Congress the means
to do whatever was </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">necessary and proper</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> to carry out the
powers expressly granted to it. Nothing now can prevent
Congress, should it choose to do so, from issuing paper money
of any description whatever, even if of absolutely no value.
The disaster that might be brought upon the country by a
rising tide of repudiation among debtors, taking its effect
through a facile and plastic Congress (as in the case of the
silver coinage in 1878), is appalling to reflect upon.
</span>
<SPAN name="toc181" id="toc181"></SPAN>
<h3><span>§ 2. If regulated by the price of Bullion, as inconvertible Currency might be safe, but not Expedient.</span></h3>
<p>
In order that the value of the currency may be
secure from being altered by design, and may be as little as
possible liable to fluctuation from accident, the articles least
liable of all known commodities to vary in their value, the
precious metals, have been made in all civilized countries
the standard of value for the circulating medium; and no
paper currency ought to exist of which the value can not be
made to conform to theirs. Nor has this fundamental maxim
ever been entirely lost sight of, even by the governments
which have most abused the power of creating inconvertible
paper. If they have not (as they generally have) professed
an intention of paying in specie at some indefinite future
time, they have at least, by giving to their paper issues the
names of their coins, made a virtual, though generally a false,
profession of intending to keep them at a value corresponding
to that of the coins. This is not impracticable, even
with an inconvertible paper. There is not, indeed, the self-acting
check which convertibility brings with it. But there
is a clear and unequivocal indication by which to judge
whether the currency is depreciated, and to what extent.
That indication is the price of the precious metals. When
holders of paper can not demand coin to be converted into
bullion, and when there is none left in circulation, bullion
rises and falls in price like other things; and if it is above
the mint price—if an ounce of gold, which would be coined
into the equivalent of [$18.60], is sold for [$20 or $25] in
paper—the value of the currency has sunk just that much
below what the value of a metallic currency would be. If,
therefore, the issue of inconvertible paper were subjected to
strict rules, one rule being that, whenever bullion rose above
the mint price, the issues should be contracted until the
market price of bullion and the mint price were again in
accordance, such a currency would not be subject to any
of the evils usually deemed inherent in an inconvertible
paper.</p>
<p>
But, also, such a system of currency would have no advantages
sufficient to recommend it to adoption. An inconvertible
currency, regulated by the price of bullion, would
conform exactly, in all its variations, to a convertible one;
and the only advantage gained would be that of exemption
from the necessity of keeping any reserve of the precious
metals, which is not a very important consideration, especially
as a government, so long as its good faith is not suspected,
need not keep so large a reserve as private issuers,
being not so liable to great and sudden demands, since there
never can be any real doubt of its solvency.</p>
<span style="font-size: 90%">
The United States since 1879 finds that a reserve of from
$130,000,000 to $140,000,000 is a sufficient reserve for outstanding
notes to the amount of $346,000,000, and greenbacks
are now at a par with gold.
</span>
<p>
Against this small advantage is to be set, in the first place,
the possibility of fraudulent tampering with the price of
bullion for the sake of acting on the currency, in the manner
of the fictitious sales of corn, to influence the averages,
so much and so justly complained of while the corn laws
were in force. But a still stronger consideration is the importance
of adhering to a simple principle, intelligible to
the most untaught capacity. Everybody can understand
convertibility; every one sees that what can be at any moment
exchanged for five [dollars] is worth five [dollars].
Regulation by the price of bullion is a more complex idea,
and does not recommend itself through the same familiar
associations. There would be nothing like the same confidence,
by the public generally, in an inconvertible currency
so regulated, as in a convertible one: and the most instructed
person might reasonably doubt whether such a rule would be
as likely to be inflexibly adhered to. The grounds of the
rule not being so well understood by the public, opinion
would probably not enforce it with as much rigidity, and,
in any circumstances of difficulty, would be likely to turn
against it; while to the Government itself a suspension of
convertibility would appear a much stronger and more extreme
measure than a relaxation of what might possibly
be considered a somewhat artificial rule. There is therefore
a great preponderance of reasons in favor of a convertible,
in preference to even the best regulated inconvertible,
currency. The temptation to over-issue, in certain
financial emergencies, is so strong, that nothing is admissible
which can tend, in however slight a degree, to weaken the
barriers that restrain it.</p>
<span style="font-size: 90%">
The French Government, in the Franco-Prussian War
(1870), issued inconvertible paper on this plan, as explained
by Mr. Mill; but, acting through the Bank of France, they conducted
their issues so successfully that the notes never depreciated
more than about one half of one per cent. But this
was a very rare management of inconvertible paper, since the
issues were actually limited as the price of gold in paper rose
above par.
</span>
<div style="break-after:column;"></div><br />