<SPAN name="toc196" id="toc196"></SPAN>
<SPAN name="pdf197" id="pdf197"></SPAN>
<h2><span>Chapter XIII. Of International Trade.</span></h2>
<SPAN name="toc198" id="toc198"></SPAN>
<h3><span>§ 1. Cost of Production not a regulator of international values. Extension of the word </span><span class="tei tei-q" style="text-align: left"><span style="font-size: 120%">“</span><span style="font-size: 120%">international.</span><span style="font-size: 120%">”</span></span></h3>
<p>
Some things it is physically impossible to produce,
except in particular circumstances of heat, soil, water, or atmosphere.
But there are many things which, though they
could be produced at home without difficulty, and in any
quantity, are yet imported from a distance. The explanation
which would be popularly given of this would be, that it is
cheaper to import than to produce them: and this is the true
reason. But this reason itself requires that a reason be given
for it. Of two things produced in the same place, if one is
cheaper than the other, the reason is that it can be produced
with less labor and capital, or, in a word, at less cost. Is this
also the reason as between things produced in different
places? Are things never imported but from places where
they can be produced with less labor (or less of the other
element of cost, time) than in the place to which they are
brought? Does the law, that permanent value is proportioned
to cost of production, hold good between commodities
produced in distant places, as it does between those produced
in adjacent places?</p>
<p>
We shall find that it does not. A thing may sometimes
be sold cheapest, by being produced in some other place
than that at which it can be produced with the smallest
amount of labor and abstinence.</p>
<p>
This could not happen between adjacent places. If the
north bank of the Thames possessed an advantage over the
south bank in the production of shoes, no shoes would be
produced on the south side; the shoemakers would remove
themselves and their capitals to the north bank, or would
have established themselves there originally; for, being competitors
in the same market with those on the north side,
they could not compensate themselves for their disadvantage
at the expense of the consumer; the amount of it would fall
entirely on their profits; and they would not long content
themselves with a smaller profit, when, by simply crossing a
river, they could increase it. But between distant places,
and especially between different countries, profits may continue
different; because persons do not usually remove themselves
or their capitals to a distant place without a very
strong motive. If capital removed to remote parts of the
world as readily, and for as small an inducement, as it moves
to another quarter of the same town—if people would transport
their manufactories to America or China whenever they
could save a small percentage in their expenses by it—profits
would be alike (or equivalent) all over the world, and all
things would be produced in the places where the same labor
and capital would produce them in greatest quantity and of
best quality. A tendency may, even now, be observed toward
such a state of things: capital is becoming more and
more cosmopolitan; there is so much greater similarity of
manners and institutions than formerly, and so much less
alienation of feeling, among the more civilized countries,
that both population and capital now move from one of
those countries to another on much less temptation than
heretofore. But there are still extraordinary differences,
both of wages and of profits, between different parts of the
world.</p>
<p>
Between all distant places, therefore, in some degree, but
especially between different countries (whether under the
same supreme government or not), there may exist great inequalities
in the return to labor and capital, without causing
them to move from one place to the other in such quantity as
to level those inequalities. The capital belonging to a country
will, to a great extent, remain in the country, even if
there be no mode of employing it in which it would not be
more productive elsewhere. Yet even a country thus circumstanced
might, and probably would, carry on trade with
other countries. It would export articles of some sort, even
to places which could make them with less labor than itself;
because those countries, supposing them to have an advantage
over it in all productions, would have a greater advantage
in some things than in others, and would find it their
interest to import the articles in which their advantage was
smallest, that they might employ more of their labor and
capital on those in which it was greatest.</p>
<span style="font-size: 90%">
It might seem that a special theory of value is required
for international trade, as compared with domestic trade, for
the particular reason that in the former there exists </span><em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">no free
movement of labor and capital</span></em><span style="font-size: 90%"> from one trading country to
another. But we shall see that no new theory is necessary.
As before pointed out,</span><SPAN id="noteref_258" name="noteref_258" href="#note_258"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">258</span></span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%"> commodities exchange for each other
at their relative costs wherever there is that free competition
which insures perfect facility of movement for labor and capital.
It has been usually assumed that capital and labor move
freely as between different parts of the same country, but
not between different countries. This, however, is not consistent
with the facts. We saw that there were non-competing
industrial groups within the same nation. Mr. Mill here,
in a pointed way, suggests this, when he speaks of </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">distant
places.</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> The addition, therefore, made to Mr. Mill's exposition
by Mr. Cairnes</span><SPAN id="noteref_259" name="noteref_259" href="#note_259"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">259</span></span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%"> is, that the word </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">international</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> (in
default of a better term) should be applied to those conditions
either within a country, or between two countries, which,
because of the actual immobility of labor and capital from one
occupation to another, furnishes a substantial interference with
industrial competition. The obstacles to the free movement of
labor and capital which produce the conditions called </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">international</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%">
are: 1. </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">Geographical distance; 2. Difference in
political institutions; 3. Difference in language, religion, and
social customs—in a word, in forms of civilization.</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> These
differences exist between Maine and Montana; or even between
two adjoining States, Ohio and Kentucky, one a free
and the other an old slave State. Labor and capital have not
in the past moved freely even across Mason and Dixon's line.
There is, therefore, no treatment of international trade and
values separate from the laws of value already laid down concerning
non-competing groups, since there is also no free competition
between all the industrial groups within a country.
</span>
<SPAN name="toc199" id="toc199"></SPAN>
<h3><span>§ 2. Interchange of commodities between distance places determined by differences not in their absolute, but in the comparative, costs of production.</span></h3>
<p>
As I have said elsewhere<SPAN id="noteref_260" name="noteref_260" href="#note_260"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">260</span></span></SPAN> after Ricardo (the thinker
who has done most toward clearing up this subject),<SPAN id="noteref_261" name="noteref_261" href="#note_261"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">261</span></span></SPAN> <span class="tei tei-q">“it is
not a difference in the <em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-style: italic">absolute</span></em> cost of production which
determines the interchange, but a difference in the <em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-style: italic">comparative</span></em>
cost. It may be to our advantage to procure iron from
Sweden in exchange for cottons, even although the mines of
England as well as her manufactories should be more productive
than those of Sweden; for if we have an advantage of
one half in cottons, and only an advantage of a quarter in
iron, and could sell our cottons to Sweden at the price which
Sweden must pay for them if she produced them herself, we
should obtain our iron with an advantage [over Sweden] of
one half, as well as our cottons. We may often, by trading
with foreigners, obtain their commodities at a smaller expense
of labor and capital than they cost to the foreigners
themselves. The bargain is still advantageous to the foreigner,
because the commodity which he receives in exchange,
though it has cost us less, would have cost him
more.”</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
This may be illustrated as follows:
</span></p>
<table summary="This is a table" cellspacing="0" class="tei tei-table" style="margin-bottom: 1.00em"><colgroup span="3"></colgroup><tbody><tr class="tei tei-row"><td class="tei tei-cell">Articles interchanged.</td><td class="tei tei-cell">England.</td><td class="tei tei-cell">Sweden.</td></tr><tr class="tei tei-row"><td class="tei tei-cell">Cotton.</td>
<td class="tei tei-cell">10 days' labor produces <span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-style: italic">x</span></span> yds.</td>
<td class="tei tei-cell">15 days' labor produces <span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-style: italic">x</span></span> yds.</td></tr><tr class="tei tei-row"><td class="tei tei-cell">Iron.</td>
<td class="tei tei-cell">12 days' labor produces <span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-style: italic">y</span></span> cwts.</td>
<td class="tei tei-cell">15 days' labor produces <span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-style: italic">y</span></span> cwts.</td></tr></tbody></table>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
Here England has the advantage over Sweden in both cotton
and iron, since she can produce </span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">x</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> yards of cotton in ten
days' labor to fifteen days in Sweden, and </span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">y</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> cwts. of iron in
twelve days' labor to fifteen days in Sweden. The ship which
takes </span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">x</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> yards of cotton to Sweden, and there exchanges it, as
may be done, for </span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">y</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> cwts. of iron, brings back to England that
which cost Sweden fifteen days' labor, while the cotton with
</span><span style="font-size: 90%">
which the iron was bought cost England only ten days' labor.
So that England also got her iron at an advantage over Sweden
of one half of ten days' labor; and yet England had an absolute
advantage over Sweden in iron of a less amount (i.e., of
one fourth of twelve days' labor). It is to be distinctly understood
that by difference in </span><em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">comparative cost</span></em><span style="font-size: 90%"> we mean a difference
in the comparative cost of producing two or more articles
in the </span><em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">same country</span></em><span style="font-size: 90%">, and not the difference of cost of the same
article in the different trading countries. In this example, for
instance, it is the difference in the comparative costs in England
of both cotton and iron (not the different costs of cotton
in England and Sweden) which gives the reason for the existence
of the foreign trade.
</span></p>
<p>
To illustrate the cases in which interchange of commodities
will not, and those in which it will, take place between
two countries, the supposition may be made that the United
States has an advantage over England in the production both
of iron and of corn. It may first be supposed that the advantage
is of equal amount in both commodities; the iron
and the corn, each of which required 100 days' labor in the
United States, requiring each 150 days' labor in England.
It would follow that the iron of 150 days' labor in England,
if sent to the United States, would be equal to the iron of
100 days' labor in the United States; if exchanged for corn,
therefore, it would exchange for the corn of only 100 days'
labor. But the corn of 100 days' labor in the United States
was supposed to be the same quantity with that of 150 days'
labor in England. With 150 days' labor in iron, therefore,
England would only get as much corn in the United States
as she could raise with 150 days' labor at home; and she
would, in importing it, have the cost of carriage besides. In
these circumstances no exchange would take place. In this
case the comparative costs of the two articles in England and
in the United States were supposed to be the same, though
the absolute costs were different; on which supposition we
see that there would be no labor saved to either country by
confining its industry to one of the two productions and importing
the other.</p>
<p>
It is otherwise when the comparative and not merely
the absolute costs of the two articles are different in the two
countries. If, while the iron produced with 100 days' labor
in the United States was produced with 150 days' labor in
England, the corn which was produced in the United States
with 100 days' labor could not be produced in England with
less than 200 days' labor, an adequate motive to exchange
would immediately arise. With a quantity of iron which
England produced with 150 days' labor, she would be able to
purchase as much corn in the United States as was there produced
with 100 days' labor; but the quantity which was there
produced with 100 days' labor would be as great as the quantity
produced in England with 200 days' labor. By importing
corn, therefore, from the United States, and paying for
it with iron, England would obtain for 150 days' labor what
would otherwise cost her 200, being a saving of 50 days'
labor on each repetition of the transaction; and not merely a
saving to England, but a saving absolutely; for it is not obtained
at the expense of the United States, who, with corn
that cost her 100 days' labor, has purchased iron which, if
produced at home, would have cost her the same. The
United States, therefore, on this supposition, loses nothing;
but also she derives no advantage from the trade, the imported
iron costing her as much as if it were made at home.
To enable the United States to gain anything by the interchange,
something must be abated from the gain of England:
the corn produced in the United States by 100 days' labor
must be able to purchase from England more iron than the
United States could produce by that amount of labor; more,
therefore, than England could produce by 150 days' labor,
England thus obtaining the corn which would have cost her
200 days at a cost exceeding 150, though short of 200.
England, therefore, no longer gains the whole of the labor
which is saved to the two jointly by trading with one another.<SPAN id="noteref_262" name="noteref_262" href="#note_262"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">262</span></span></SPAN></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
The case in which both England and the United States
would gain from the trade may be thus briefly shown:
</span></p>
<table summary="This is a table" cellspacing="0" class="tei tei-table" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><colgroup span="3"></colgroup><tbody><tr class="tei tei-row"><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">Articles interchanged.</span></td><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">United States.</span></td>
<td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">England.</span></td></tr><tr class="tei tei-row"><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">Corn.</span></td>
<td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">100 days' labor produces </span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">x</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> bus.</span></td>
<td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">200 days' labor produces </span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">x</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> bus.</span></td></tr><tr class="tei tei-row"><td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">Iron.</span></td>
<td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">125 days' labor produces </span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">y</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> tons.</span></td>
<td class="tei tei-cell"><span style="font-size: 90%">150 days' labor produces </span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">y</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> tons.</span></td></tr></tbody></table>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
The ship which carries </span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">x</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> bushels of corn from the United
States to England can there exchange it for at least </span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">y</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> tons of
iron (costing England 150 days' labor, since </span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">x</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> bushels in England
would cost 200 days' labor), and bring it home, gaining for the
United States the difference between the 100 days' labor in
corn, paid for the </span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">y</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> tons of iron, and the 125 days which the
iron would have cost here if produced at home. In this case
the United States has an advantage over England in both corn
and iron, but still an international trade will spring up, because
the United States will derive a gain owing to the less cost of
corn as compared with the cost of iron. Our </span><em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">comparative</span></em><span style="font-size: 90%"> advantage
is in corn. England, also, by sending to the United
States </span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">y</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> tons of iron, gets
in return for it </span><span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">x</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> bushels of corn.
To produce the corn herself would have cost her 200 days' labor,
but she bought that corn by only 150 days' labor spent on
iron. England's </span><em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">comparative</span></em><span style="font-size: 90%"> advantage is in iron. Then both
countries will gain.
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
Mr. Bowen</span><SPAN id="noteref_263" name="noteref_263" href="#note_263"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">263</span></span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%"> gives an instance of international trade where
one country has the advantage in both of the commodities
entering into the exchange: </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">The inhabitants of Barbadoes,
favored by their tropical climate and fertile soil, can raise
provisions cheaper than we can in the United States. And
yet Barbadoes buys nearly all her provisions from this country.
Why is this so? Because, though Barbadoes has the
advantage over us in the ability to raise provisions cheaply,
she has a still greater advantage over us in her power to produce
sugar and molasses. If she has an advantage of one
fourth in raising provisions, she has an advantage of one half
in regard to products exclusively tropical; and it is better
for her to employ all her labor and capital in that branch
of production in which her advantage is greatest. She can
thus, by trading with us, obtain our breadstuffs and meat at a
smaller expense of labor and capital than they cost ourselves.
If, for instance, a barrel of flour costs ten days' labor in the
United States and only eight days' labor in Barbadoes, the
people of Barbadoes can still profitably buy the flour from this
</span><span style="font-size: 90%">
country, if they can pay for it with sugar which cost them only
six days' labor; and the people of this country can profitably
sell them the flour, or buy from them the sugar, provided the
sugar, if raised in the United States, would cost eleven days'
labor.... The United States receive sugar, which would have
cost them eleven days' labor, by paying for it with flour which
costs them but ten days. Barbadoes receives flour, which would
have cost her eight days' labor, by paying for it with sugar
which costs her but six days. If Barbadoes produced both
commodities with greater facility, but greater in precisely the
same degree, there would be no motive for interchange.</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
It may be said, however, that in practice no business-man
considers the question of </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">comparative cost</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> in making shipments
of goods abroad; that all he thinks of is whether the
price here, for example, is less than it is in London. And yet
the very fact that the prices are less here implies that gold is
of high value relatively to the given commodity; while in
London, if money is to be sent back in payment, and if prices
are high there, that implies that gold is there of less comparative
value than commodities, and consequently that gold is the
cheapest article to send to the United States. The doctrine,
then, is as true of gold, or the precious metals, as it is of other
commodities.</span><SPAN id="noteref_264" name="noteref_264" href="#note_264"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">264</span></span></SPAN><span style="font-size: 90%">
It may be stated in the following language of
Mr. Cairnes: </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">The proximate condition determining international
exchange is the state of comparative prices in the exchanging
countries as regards the commodities which form
the subject of the trade. But comparative prices within
the limits of each country are determined by two distinct
principles—within the range of effective industrial competition,
by cost of production; outside that range, by reciprocal
demand.</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><SPAN id="noteref_265" name="noteref_265" href="#note_265"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">265</span></span></SPAN></p>
<SPAN name="toc200" id="toc200"></SPAN>
<h3><span>§ 3. The direct benefits of commerce consist in increased Efficiency of the productive powers of the World.</span></h3>
<p>
From this exposition we perceive in what consists
the benefit of international exchange, or, in other words,
foreign commerce. Setting aside its enabling countries to
obtain commodities which they could not themselves produce
at all, its advantage consists in a more efficient employment
of the productive forces of the world. If two countries
which traded together attempted, as far as was physically
possible, to produce for themselves what they now import
from one another, the labor and capital of the two countries
would not be so productive, the two together would not obtain
from their industry so great a quantity of commodities,
as when each employs itself in producing, both for itself and
for the other, the things in which its labor is relatively most
efficient. The addition thus made to the produce of the two
combined constitutes the advantage of the trade. It is possible
that one of the two countries may be altogether inferior
to the other in productive capacities, and that its labor and
capital could be employed to greatest advantage by being removed
bodily to the other. The labor and capital which
have been sunk in rendering Holland habitable would have
produced a much greater return if transported to America or
Ireland. The produce of the whole world would be greater,
or the labor less, than it is, if everything were produced
where there is the greatest absolute facility for its production.
But nations do not, at least in modern times, emigrate
<span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-style: italic">en masse</span></span>; and, while the labor and capital of a country remain
in the country, they are most beneficially employed in
producing, for foreign markets as well as for its own, the
things in which it lies under the least disadvantage, if there
be none in which it possesses an advantage.</p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
The fundamental ground on which all trade, or all exchange
of commodities, rests, is division of labor, or separation of employments.
Beyond the ordinary gain from division of labor,
arising from increased dexterity, there exist gains arising from
the development of </span><span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">the special capacities or resources possessed
by particular individuals or localities.</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%"> International
exchanges call out chiefly the special advantages offered by
particular </span><em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">localities</span></em><span style="font-size: 90%"> for the prosecution of particular industries.
</span></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em">
<span class="tei tei-q"><span style="font-size: 90%">“</span><span style="font-size: 90%">The only case, indeed, in which </span><em class="tei tei-emph"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">personal aptitudes</span></em><span style="font-size: 90%"> go for
much in the commerce of nations is where the nations concerned
occupy different grades in the scale of civilization....
The most striking example which the world has ever seen of a
foreign trade determined by the peculiar personal qualities of
those engaged in ministering to it is that which was furnished
by the Southern States of the American Union previous to the
abolition of slavery. The effect of that institution was to give
a very distinct industrial character to the laboring population
of those States which unfitted them for all but a very limited
number of occupations, but gave them a certain special fitness
for these. Almost the entire industry of the country was consequently
</span><span style="font-size: 90%">
turned to the production of two or three crude commodities,
in raising which the industry of slaves was found to
be effective; and these were used, through an exchange with
foreign countries, as the means of supplying the inhabitants
with all other requisites.... In the main, however, it would
seem that this cause [personal aptitudes] does not go for very
much in international commerce.</span><span style="font-size: 90%">”</span></span><SPAN id="noteref_266" name="noteref_266" href="#note_266"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">266</span></span></SPAN></p>
<p class="tei tei-p" style="margin-bottom: 0.90em"><span style="font-size: 90%">
In brief, then, international trade is but an extension of the
principle of division of labor; and the gains to increased productiveness,
arising from the latter, are exactly the same as
those from the former.
</span></p>
<SPAN name="toc201" id="toc201"></SPAN>
<h3><span>§ 4. —Not in a Vent for exports, nor in the gains of Merchants.</span></h3>
<p>
According to the doctrine now stated, the only direct
advantage of foreign commerce consists in the imports. A
country obtains things which it either could not have produced
at all, or which it must have produced at a greater
expense of capital and labor than the cost of the things
which it exports to pay for them. It thus obtains a more
ample supply of the commodities it wants, for the same labor
and capital; or the same supply, for less labor and capital,
leaving the surplus disposable to produce other things. The
vulgar theory disregards this benefit and deems the advantage
of commerce to reside in the exports: as if not what a country
obtains, but what it parts with, by its foreign trade, was
supposed to constitute the gain to it. An extended market
for its produce—an abundant consumption for its goods—a
vent for its surplus—are the phrases by which it has been
customary to designate the uses and recommendations of
commerce with foreign countries. This notion is intelligible,
when we consider that the authors and leaders of opinion on
mercantile questions have always hitherto been the selling
class. It is in truth a surviving relic of the Mercantile
Theory, according to which, money being the only wealth,
selling, or, in other words, exchanging goods for money,
was (to countries without mines of their own) the only
way of growing rich—and importation of goods, that is to
say, parting with money, was so much subtracted from the
benefit.</p>
<p>
The notion that money alone is wealth has been long
defunct, but it has left many of its progeny behind it. Adam
Smith's theory of the benefit of foreign trade was, that it
afforded an outlet for the surplus produce of a country, and
enabled a portion of the capital of the country to replace itself
with a profit. The expression, surplus produce, seems
to imply that a country is under some kind of necessity of
producing the corn or cloth which it exports; so that the
portion which it does not itself consume, if not wanted and
consumed elsewhere, would either be produced in sheer
waste, or, if it were not produced, the corresponding portion
of capital would remain idle, and the mass of productions in
the country would be diminished by so much. Either of
these suppositions would be entirely erroneous. The country
produces an exportable article in excess of its own wants
from no inherent necessity, but as the cheapest mode of supplying
itself with other things. If prevented from exporting
this surplus, it would cease to produce it, and would no
longer import anything, being unable to give an equivalent;
but the labor and capital which had been employed in producing
with a view to exportation would find employment
in producing those desirable objects which were previously
brought from abroad; or, if some of them could not be produced,
in producing substitutes for them. These articles
would, of course, be produced at a greater cost than that of
the things with which they had previously been purchased
from foreign countries. But the value and price of the
articles would rise in proportion; and the capital would
just as much be replaced, with the ordinary profit, from
the returns, as it was when employed in producing for the
foreign market. The only losers (after the temporary inconvenience
of the change) would be the consumers of the
heretofore imported articles, who would be obliged either
to do without them, consuming in lieu of them something
which they did not like as well, or to pay a higher price
for them than before.</p>
<p>
If it be said that the capital now employed in foreign
trade could not find employment in supplying the home
market, I might reply that this is the fallacy of general
over-production, discussed in a former chapter; but the thing
is in this particular case too evident to require an appeal to
any general theory. We not only see that the capital of the
merchant would find employment, but we see what employment.
There would be employment created, equal to that
which would be taken away. Exportation ceasing, importation
to an equal value would cease also, and all that part
of the income of the country which had been expended in
imported commodities would be ready to expend itself on
the same things produced at home, or on others instead of
them. Commerce is virtually a mode of cheapening production;
and in all such cases the consumer is the person
ultimately benefited; the dealer, in the end, is sure to get
his profit, whether the buyer obtains much or little for his
money.</p>
<span class="tei tei-hi"><span style="font-size: 90%; font-style: italic">E converso</span></span><span style="font-size: 90%">, if for any reason, such as a removal of duties,
capital should be withdrawn from the production of articles
consumed at home, and imported commodities should entirely
take their place, the very importation of the foreign commodities
would imply that an increased corresponding production
was going on in this country with which to pay for the imported
goods. The capital thus thrown out of employment in an
industry in which we had no comparative advantage (when
competition became free) would necessarily be employed in
the industries in which we had an advantage, and would supply—and
the transferred capital would be the only means of supplying—the
commodities which would be sent abroad to pay
for those, which by the supposition are now imported, but were
formerly produced at home. The result is a greater productiveness
of industry, and so a greater sum from which both labor
and capital may be rewarded. Whenever capital, unrestrained
by artificial support, leaves one employment as unprofitable, it
means that that employment is naturally, and in itself, less
productive than the usual run of other industries in the country,
and so less profitable to both labor and capital than the
majority of other occupations.
</span>
<SPAN name="toc202" id="toc202"></SPAN>
<h3><span>§ 5. Indirect benefits of Commerce, Economical and Moral; still greater than the Direct.</span></h3>
<p>
Such, then, is the direct economical advantage of
foreign trade. But there are, besides, indirect effects, which
must be counted as benefits of a high order. (1) One is, the
tendency of every extension of the market to improve the
processes of production. A country which produces for a
larger market than its own can introduce a more extended
division of labor, can make greater use of machinery, and
is more likely to make inventions and improvements in the
processes of production. Whatever causes a greater quantity
of anything to be produced in the same place tends to the
general increase of the productive powers of the
world.<SPAN id="noteref_267" name="noteref_267" href="#note_267"><span class="tei tei-noteref"><span style="font-size: 60%; vertical-align: super">267</span></span></SPAN>
There is (2) another consideration, principally applicable to
an early stage of industrial advancement. The opening of
a foreign trade, by making them acquainted with new objects,
or tempting them by the easier acquisition of things
which they had not previously thought attainable, sometimes
works a sort of industrial revolution in a country whose resources
were previously undeveloped for want of energy and
ambition in the people; inducing those who were satisfied
with scanty comforts and little work to work harder for the
gratification of their new tastes, and even to save, and accumulate
capital, for the still more complete satisfaction of
those tastes at a future time.</p>
<p>
But (3) the economical advantages of commerce are surpassed
in importance by those of its effects which are intellectual
and moral. It is hardly possible to overrate the
value, in the present low state of human improvement, of
placing human beings in contact with persons dissimilar to
themselves, and with modes of thought and action unlike
those with which they are familiar. Commerce is now,
what war once was, the principal source of this contact.
Such communication has always been, and is peculiarly in
the present age, one of the primary sources of progress.
Finally, (4) commerce first taught nations to see with goodwill
the wealth and prosperity of one another. Before, the
patriot, unless sufficiently advanced in culture to feel the
world his country, wished all countries weak, poor, and ill-governed
but his own: he now sees in their wealth and
progress a direct source of wealth and progress to his own
country. It is commerce which is rapidly rendering war
obsolete, by strengthening and multiplying the personal interests
which are in natural opposition to it. And it may
be said without exaggeration that the great extent and rapid
increase of international trade, in being the principal guarantee
of the peace of the world, is the great permanent security
for the uninterrupted progress of the ideas, the institutions,
and the character of the human race.</p>
<hr class="page" />
<div style="break-after:column;"></div><br />