<p><SPAN name="link2HCH0004" id="link2HCH0004"></SPAN></p>
<h2> Chapter Four ~~ Conspicuous Consumption </h2>
<p>In what has been said of the evolution of the vicarious leisure class and
its differentiation from the general body of the working classes,
reference has been made to a further division of labour,—that
between the different servant classes. One portion of the servant class,
chiefly those persons whose occupation is vicarious leisure, come to
undertake a new, subsidiary range of duties—the vicarious
consumption of goods. The most obvious form in which this consumption
occurs is seen in the wearing of liveries and the occupation of spacious
servants' quarters. Another, scarcely less obtrusive or less effective
form of vicarious consumption, and a much more widely prevalent one, is
the consumption of food, clothing, dwelling, and furniture by the lady and
the rest of the domestic establishment.</p>
<p>But already at a point in economic evolution far antedating the emergence
of the lady, specialised consumption of goods as an evidence of pecuniary
strength had begun to work out in a more or less elaborate system. The
beginning of a differentiation in consumption even antedates the
appearance of anything that can fairly be called pecuniary strength. It is
traceable back to the initial phase of predatory culture, and there is
even a suggestion that an incipient differentiation in this respect lies
back of the beginnings of the predatory life. This most primitive
differentiation in the consumption of goods is like the later
differentiation with which we are all so intimately familiar, in that it
is largely of a ceremonial character, but unlike the latter it does not
rest on a difference in accumulated wealth. The utility of consumption as
an evidence of wealth is to be classed as a derivative growth. It is an
adaption to a new end, by a selective process, of a distinction previously
existing and well established in men's habits of thought.</p>
<p>In the earlier phases of the predatory culture the only economic
differentiation is a broad distinction between an honourable superior
class made up of the able-bodied men on the one side, and a base inferior
class of labouring women on the other. According to the ideal scheme of
life in force at the time it is the office of the men to consume what the
women produce. Such consumption as falls to the women is merely incidental
to their work; it is a means to their continued labour, and not a
consumption directed to their own comfort and fulness of life.
Unproductive consumption of goods is honourable, primarily as a mark of
prowess and a perquisite of human dignity; secondarily it becomes
substantially honourable to itself, especially the consumption of the more
desirable things. The consumption of choice articles of food, and
frequently also of rare articles of adornment, becomes tabu to the women
and children; and if there is a base (servile) class of men, the tabu
holds also for them. With a further advance in culture this tabu may
change into simple custom of a more or less rigorous character; but
whatever be the theoretical basis of the distinction which is maintained,
whether it be a tabu or a larger conventionality, the features of the
conventional scheme of consumption do not change easily. When the
quasi-peaceable stage of industry is reached, with its fundamental
institution of chattel slavery, the general principle, more or less
rigorously applied, is that the base, industrious class should consume
only what may be necessary to their subsistence. In the nature of things,
luxuries and the comforts of life belong to the leisure class. Under the
tabu, certain victuals, and more particularly certain beverages, are
strictly reserved for the use of the superior class.</p>
<p>The ceremonial differentiation of the dietary is best seen in the use of
intoxicating beverages and narcotics. If these articles of consumption are
costly, they are felt to be noble and honorific. Therefore the base
classes, primarily the women, practice an enforced continence with respect
to these stimulants, except in countries where they are obtainable at a
very low cost. From archaic times down through all the length of the
patriarchal regime it has been the office of the women to prepare and
administer these luxuries, and it has been the perquisite of the men of
gentle birth and breeding to consume them. Drunkenness and the other
pathological consequences of the free use of stimulants therefore tend in
their turn to become honorific, as being a mark, at the second remove, of
the superior status of those who are able to afford the indulgence.
Infirmities induced by over-indulgence are among some peoples freely
recognised as manly attributes. It has even happened that the name for
certain diseased conditions of the body arising from such an origin has
passed into everyday speech as a synonym for "noble" or "gentle". It is
only at a relatively early stage of culture that the symptoms of expensive
vice are conventionally accepted as marks of a superior status, and so
tend to become virtues and command the deference of the community; but the
reputability that attaches to certain expensive vices long retains so much
of its force as to appreciably lesson the disapprobation visited upon the
men of the wealthy or noble class for any excessive indulgence. The same
invidious distinction adds force to the current disapproval of any
indulgence of this kind on the part of women, minors, and inferiors. This
invidious traditional distinction has not lost its force even among the
more advanced peoples of today. Where the example set by the leisure class
retains its imperative force in the regulation of the conventionalities,
it is observable that the women still in great measure practise the same
traditional continence with regard to stimulants.</p>
<p>This characterisation of the greater continence in the use of stimulants
practised by the women of the reputable classes may seem an excessive
refinement of logic at the expense of common sense. But facts within easy
reach of any one who cares to know them go to say that the greater
abstinence of women is in some part due to an imperative conventionality;
and this conventionality is, in a general way, strongest where the
patriarchal tradition—the tradition that the woman is a chattel—has
retained its hold in greatest vigour. In a sense which has been greatly
qualified in scope and rigour, but which has by no means lost its meaning
even yet, this tradition says that the woman, being a chattel, should
consume only what is necessary to her sustenance,—except so far as
her further consumption contributes to the comfort or the good repute of
her master. The consumption of luxuries, in the true sense, is a
consumption directed to the comfort of the consumer himself, and is,
therefore, a mark of the master. Any such consumption by others can take
place only on a basis of sufferance. In communities where the popular
habits of thought have been profoundly shaped by the patriarchal tradition
we may accordingly look for survivals of the tabu on luxuries at least to
the extent of a conventional deprecation of their use by the unfree and
dependent class. This is more particularly true as regards certain
luxuries, the use of which by the dependent class would detract sensibly
from the comfort or pleasure of their masters, or which are held to be of
doubtful legitimacy on other grounds. In the apprehension of the great
conservative middle class of Western civilisation the use of these various
stimulants is obnoxious to at least one, if not both, of these objections;
and it is a fact too significant to be passed over that it is precisely
among these middle classes of the Germanic culture, with their strong
surviving sense of the patriarchal proprieties, that the women are to the
greatest extent subject to a qualified tabu on narcotics and alcoholic
beverages. With many qualifications—with more qualifications as the
patriarchal tradition has gradually weakened—the general rule is
felt to be right and binding that women should consume only for the
benefit of their masters. The objection of course presents itself that
expenditure on women's dress and household paraphernalia is an obvious
exception to this rule; but it will appear in the sequel that this
exception is much more obvious than substantial. During the earlier stages
of economic development, consumption of goods without stint, especially
consumption of the better grades of goods,—ideally all consumption
in excess of the subsistence minimum,—pertains normally to the
leisure class. This restriction tends to disappear, at least formally,
after the later peaceable stage has been reached, with private ownership
of goods and an industrial system based on wage labour or on the petty
household economy. But during the earlier quasi-peaceable stage, when so
many of the traditions through which the institution of a leisure class
has affected the economic life of later times were taking form and
consistency, this principle has had the force of a conventional law. It
has served as the norm to which consumption has tended to conform, and any
appreciable departure from it is to be regarded as an aberrant form, sure
to be eliminated sooner or later in the further course of development.</p>
<p>The quasi-peaceable gentleman of leisure, then, not only consumes of the
staff of life beyond the minimum required for subsistence and physical
efficiency, but his consumption also undergoes a specialisation as regards
the quality of the goods consumed. He consumes freely and of the best, in
food, drink, narcotics, shelter, services, ornaments, apparel, weapons and
accoutrements, amusements, amulets, and idols or divinities. In the
process of gradual amelioration which takes place in the articles of his
consumption, the motive principle and proximate aim of innovation is no
doubt the higher efficiency of the improved and more elaborate products
for personal comfort and well-being. But that does not remain the sole
purpose of their consumption. The canon of reputability is at hand and
seizes upon such innovations as are, according to its standard, fit to
survive. Since the consumption of these more excellent goods is an
evidence of wealth, it becomes honorific; and conversely, the failure to
consume in due quantity and quality becomes a mark of inferiority and
demerit.</p>
<p>This growth of punctilious discrimination as to qualitative excellence in
eating, drinking, etc. presently affects not only the manner of life, but
also the training and intellectual activity of the gentleman of leisure.
He is no longer simply the successful, aggressive male,—the man of
strength, resource, and intrepidity. In order to avoid stultification he
must also cultivate his tastes, for it now becomes incumbent on him to
discriminate with some nicety between the noble and the ignoble in
consumable goods. He becomes a connoisseur in creditable viands of various
degrees of merit, in manly beverages and trinkets, in seemly apparel and
architecture, in weapons, games, dancers, and the narcotics. This
cultivation of aesthetic faculty requires time and application, and the
demands made upon the gentleman in this direction therefore tend to change
his life of leisure into a more or less arduous application to the
business of learning how to live a life of ostensible leisure in a
becoming way. Closely related to the requirement that the gentleman must
consume freely and of the right kind of goods, there is the requirement
that he must know how to consume them in a seemly manner. His life of
leisure must be conducted in due form. Hence arise good manners in the way
pointed out in an earlier chapter. High-bred manners and ways of living
are items of conformity to the norm of conspicuous leisure and conspicuous
consumption.</p>
<p>Conspicuous consumption of valuable goods is a means of reputability to
the gentleman of leisure. As wealth accumulates on his hands, his own
unaided effort will not avail to sufficiently put his opulence in evidence
by this method. The aid of friends and competitors is therefore brought in
by resorting to the giving of valuable presents and expensive feasts and
entertainments. Presents and feasts had probably another origin than that
of naive ostentation, but they required their utility for this purpose
very early, and they have retained that character to the present; so that
their utility in this respect has now long been the substantial ground on
which these usages rest. Costly entertainments, such as the potlatch or
the ball, are peculiarly adapted to serve this end. The competitor with
whom the entertainer wishes to institute a comparison is, by this method,
made to serve as a means to the end. He consumes vicariously for his host
at the same time that he is witness to the consumption of that excess of
good things which his host is unable to dispose of single-handed, and he
is also made to witness his host's facility in etiquette.</p>
<p>In the giving of costly entertainments other motives, of more genial kind,
are of course also present. The custom of festive gatherings probably
originated in motives of conviviality and religion; these motives are also
present in the later development, but they do not continue to be the sole
motives. The latter-day leisure-class festivities and entertainments may
continue in some slight degree to serve the religious need and in a higher
degree the needs of recreation and conviviality, but they also serve an
invidious purpose; and they serve it none the less effectually for having
a colorable non-invidious ground in these more avowable motives. But the
economic effect of these social amenities is not therefore lessened,
either in the vicarious consumption of goods or in the exhibition of
difficult and costly achievements in etiquette.</p>
<p>As wealth accumulates, the leisure class develops further in function and
structure, and there arises a differentiation within the class. There is a
more or less elaborate system of rank and grades. This differentiation is
furthered by the inheritance of wealth and the consequent inheritance of
gentility. With the inheritance of gentility goes the inheritance of
obligatory leisure; and gentility of a sufficient potency to entail a life
of leisure may be inherited without the complement of wealth required to
maintain a dignified leisure. Gentle blood may be transmitted without
goods enough to afford a reputably free consumption at one's ease. Hence
results a class of impecunious gentlemen of leisure, incidentally referred
to already. These half-caste gentlemen of leisure fall into a system of
hierarchical gradations. Those who stand near the higher and the highest
grades of the wealthy leisure class, in point of birth, or in point of
wealth, or both, outrank the remoter-born and the pecuniarily weaker.
These lower grades, especially the impecunious, or marginal, gentlemen of
leisure, affiliate themselves by a system of dependence or fealty to the
great ones; by so doing they gain an increment of repute, or of the means
with which to lead a life of leisure, from their patron. They become his
courtiers or retainers, servants; and being fed and countenanced by their
patron they are indices of his rank and vicarious consumer of his
superfluous wealth. Many of these affiliated gentlemen of leisure are at
the same time lesser men of substance in their own right; so that some of
them are scarcely at all, others only partially, to be rated as vicarious
consumers. So many of them, however, as make up the retainer and
hangers-on of the patron may be classed as vicarious consumer without
qualification. Many of these again, and also many of the other aristocracy
of less degree, have in turn attached to their persons a more or less
comprehensive group of vicarious consumer in the persons of their wives
and children, their servants, retainers, etc.</p>
<p>Throughout this graduated scheme of vicarious leisure and vicarious
consumption the rule holds that these offices must be performed in some
such manner, or under some such circumstance or insignia, as shall point
plainly to the master to whom this leisure or consumption pertains, and to
whom therefore the resulting increment of good repute of right inures. The
consumption and leisure executed by these persons for their master or
patron represents an investment on his part with a view to an increase of
good fame. As regards feasts and largesses this is obvious enough, and the
imputation of repute to the host or patron here takes place immediately,
on the ground of common notoriety. Where leisure and consumption is
performed vicariously by henchmen and retainers, imputation of the
resulting repute to the patron is effected by their residing near his
person so that it may be plain to all men from what source they draw. As
the group whose good esteem is to be secured in this way grows larger,
more patent means are required to indicate the imputation of merit for the
leisure performed, and to this end uniforms, badges, and liveries come
into vogue. The wearing of uniforms or liveries implies a considerable
degree of dependence, and may even be said to be a mark of servitude, real
or ostensible. The wearers of uniforms and liveries may be roughly divided
into two classes-the free and the servile, or the noble and the ignoble.
The services performed by them are likewise divisible into noble and
ignoble. Of course the distinction is not observed with strict consistency
in practice; the less debasing of the base services and the less honorific
of the noble functions are not infrequently merged in the same person. But
the general distinction is not on that account to be overlooked. What may
add some perplexity is the fact that this fundamental distinction between
noble and ignoble, which rests on the nature of the ostensible service
performed, is traversed by a secondary distinction into honorific and
humiliating, resting on the rank of the person for whom the service is
performed or whose livery is worn. So, those offices which are by right
the proper employment of the leisure class are noble; such as government,
fighting, hunting, the care of arms and accoutrements, and the like—in
short, those which may be classed as ostensibly predatory employments. On
the other hand, those employments which properly fall to the industrious
class are ignoble; such as handicraft or other productive labor, menial
services and the like. But a base service performed for a person of very
high degree may become a very honorific office; as for instance the office
of a Maid of Honor or of a Lady in Waiting to the Queen, or the King's
Master of the Horse or his Keeper of the Hounds. The two offices last
named suggest a principle of some general bearing. Whenever, as in these
cases, the menial service in question has to do directly with the primary
leisure employments of fighting and hunting, it easily acquires a
reflected honorific character. In this way great honor may come to attach
to an employment which in its own nature belongs to the baser sort. In the
later development of peaceable industry, the usage of employing an idle
corps of uniformed men-at-arms gradually lapses. Vicarious consumption by
dependents bearing the insignia of their patron or master narrows down to
a corps of liveried menials. In a heightened degree, therefore, the livery
comes to be a badge of servitude, or rather servility. Something of a
honorific character always attached to the livery of the armed retainer,
but this honorific character disappears when the livery becomes the
exclusive badge of the menial. The livery becomes obnoxious to nearly all
who are required to wear it. We are yet so little removed from a state of
effective slavery as still to be fully sensitive to the sting of any
imputation of servility. This antipathy asserts itself even in the case of
the liveries or uniforms which some corporations prescribe as the
distinctive dress of their employees. In this country the aversion even
goes the length of discrediting—in a mild and uncertain way—those
government employments, military and civil, which require the wearing of a
livery or uniform.</p>
<div style="break-after:column;"></div><br />