<p>In all this latter-day range of leisure-class activities that proceed on
the basis of a non-invidious and non-religious interest, it is to be noted
that the women participate more actively and more persistently than the
men—except, of course, in the case of such works as require a large
expenditure of means. The dependent pecuniary position of the women
disables them for work requiring large expenditure. As regards the general
range of ameliorative work, the members of the priesthood or clergy of the
less naively devout sects, or the secularized denominations, are
associated with the class of women. This is as the theory would have it.
In other economic relations, also, this clergy stands in a somewhat
equivocal position between the class of women and that of the men engaged
in economic pursuits. By tradition and by the prevalent sense of the
proprieties, both the clergy and the women of the well-to-do classes are
placed in the position of a vicarious leisure class; with both classes the
characteristic relation which goes to form the habits of thought of the
class is a relation of subservience—that is to say, an economic
relation conceived in personal terms; in both classes there is
consequently perceptible a special proneness to construe phenomena in
terms of personal relation rather than of causal sequence; both classes
are so inhibited by the canons of decency from the ceremonially unclean
processes of the lucrative or productive occupations as to make
participation in the industrial life process of today a moral
impossibility for them. The result of this ceremonial exclusion from
productive effort of the vulgar sort is to draft a relatively large share
of the energies of the modern feminine and priestly classes into the
service of other interests than the self-regarding one. The code leaves no
alternative direction in which the impulse to purposeful action may find
expression. The effect of a consistent inhibition on industrially useful
activity in the case of the leisure-class women shows itself in a restless
assertion of the impulse to workmanship in other directions than that of
business activity. As has been noticed already, the everyday life of the
well-to-do women and the clergy contains a larger element of status than
that of the average of the men, especially than that of the men engaged in
the modern industrial occupations proper. Hence the devout attitude
survives in a better state of preservation among these classes than among
the common run of men in the modern communities. Hence an appreciable
share of the energy which seeks expression in a non-lucrative employment
among these members of the vicarious leisure classes may be expected to
eventuate in devout observances and works of piety. Hence, in part, the
excess of the devout proclivity in women, spoken of in the last chapter.
But it is more to the present point to note the effect of this proclivity
in shaping the action and coloring the purposes of the non-lucrative
movements and organizations here under discussion. Where this devout
coloring is present it lowers the immediate efficiency of the
organizations for any economic end to which their efforts may be directed.
Many organizations, charitable and ameliorative, divide their attention
between the devotional and the secular well-being of the people whose
interests they aim to further. It can scarcely be doubted that if they
were to give an equally serious attention and effort undividedly to the
secular interests of these people, the immediate economic value of their
work should be appreciably higher than it is. It might of course similarly
be said, if this were the place to say it, that the immediate efficiency
of these works of amelioration for the devout might be greater if it were
not hampered with the secular motives and aims which are usually present.</p>
<p>Some deduction is to be made from the economic value of this class of
non-invidious enterprise, on account of the intrusion of the devotional
interest. But there are also deductions to be made on account of the
presence of other alien motives which more or less broadly traverse the
economic trend of this non-emulative expression of the instinct of
workmanship. To such an extent is this seen to be true on a closer
scrutiny, that, when all is told, it may even appear that this general
class of enterprises is of an altogether dubious economic value—as
measured in terms of the fullness or facility of life of the individuals
or classes to whose amelioration the enterprise is directed. For instance,
many of the efforts now in reputable vogue for the amelioration of the
indigent population of large cities are of the nature, in great part, of a
mission of culture. It is by this means sought to accelerate the rate of
speed at which given elements of the upper-class culture find acceptance
in the everyday scheme of life of the lower classes. The solicitude of
"settlements," for example, is in part directed to enhance the industrial
efficiency of the poor and to teach them the more adequate utilization of
the means at hand; but it is also no less consistently directed to the
inculcation, by precept and example, of certain punctilios of upper-class
propriety in manners and customs. The economic substance of these
proprieties will commonly be found on scrutiny to be a conspicuous waste
of time and goods. Those good people who go out to humanize the poor are
commonly, and advisedly, extremely scrupulous and silently insistent in
matters of decorum and the decencies of life. They are commonly persons of
an exemplary life and gifted with a tenacious insistence on ceremonial
cleanness in the various items of their daily consumption. The cultural or
civilizing efficacy of this inculcation of correct habits of thought with
respect to the consumption of time and commodities is scarcely to be
overrated; nor is its economic value to the individual who acquires these
higher and more reputable ideals inconsiderable. Under the circumstances
of the existing pecuniary culture, the reputability, and consequently the
success, of the individual is in great measure dependent on his
proficiency in demeanor and methods of consumption that argue habitual
waste of time and goods. But as regards the ulterior economic bearing of
this training in worthier methods of life, it is to be said that the
effect wrought is in large part a substitution of costlier or less
efficient methods of accomplishing the same material results, in relations
where the material result is the fact of substantial economic value. The
propaganda of culture is in great part an inculcation of new tastes, or
rather of a new schedule of proprieties, which have been adapted to the
upper-class scheme of life under the guidance of the leisure-class
formulation of the principles of status and pecuniary decency. This new
schedule of proprieties is intruded into the lower-class scheme of life
from the code elaborated by an element of the population whose life lies
outside the industrial process; and this intrusive schedule can scarcely
be expected to fit the exigencies of life for these lower classes more
adequately than the schedule already in vogue among them, and especially
not more adequately than the schedule which they are themselves working
out under the stress of modern industrial life.</p>
<p>All this of course does not question the fact that the proprieties of the
substituted schedule are more decorous than those which they displace. The
doubt which presents itself is simply a doubt as to the economic
expediency of this work of regeneration—that is to say, the economic
expediency in that immediate and material bearing in which the effects of
the change can be ascertained with some degree of confidence, and as
viewed from the standpoint not of the individual but of the facility of
life of the collectivity. For an appreciation of the economic expediency
of these enterprises of amelioration, therefore, their effective work is
scarcely to be taken at its face value, even where the aim of the
enterprise is primarily an economic one and where the interest on which it
proceeds is in no sense self-regarding or invidious. The economic reform
wrought is largely of the nature of a permutation in the methods of
conspicuous waste.</p>
<p>But something further is to be said with respect to the character of the
disinterested motives and canons of procedure in all work of this class
that is affected by the habits of thought characteristic of the pecuniary
culture; and this further consideration may lead to a further
qualification of the conclusions already reached. As has been seen in an
earlier chapter, the canons of reputability or decency under the pecuniary
culture insist on habitual futility of effort as the mark of a pecuniarily
blameless life. There results not only a habit of disesteem of useful
occupations, but there results also what is of more decisive consequence
in guiding the action of any organized body of people that lays claim to
social good repute. There is a tradition which requires that one should
not be vulgarly familiar with any of the processes or details that have to
do with the material necessities of life. One may meritoriously show a
quantitative interest in the well-being of the vulgar, through
subscriptions or through work on managing committees and the like. One
may, perhaps even more meritoriously, show solicitude in general and in
detail for the cultural welfare of the vulgar, in the way of contrivances
for elevating their tastes and affording them opportunities for spiritual
amelioration. But one should not betray an intimate knowledge of the
material circumstances of vulgar life, or of the habits of thought of the
vulgar classes, such as would effectually direct the efforts of these
organizations to a materially useful end. This reluctance to avow an
unduly intimate knowledge of the lower-class conditions of life in detail
of course prevails in very different degrees in different individuals; but
there is commonly enough of it present collectively in any organization of
the kind in question profoundly to influence its course of action. By its
cumulative action in shaping the usage and precedents of any such body,
this shrinking from an imputation of unseemly familiarity with vulgar life
tends gradually to set aside the initial motives of the enterprise, in
favor of certain guiding principles of good repute, ultimately reducible
to terms of pecuniary merit. So that in an organization of long standing
the initial motive of furthering the facility of life in these classes
comes gradually to be an ostensible motive only, and the vulgarly
effective work of the organization tends to obsolescence.</p>
<p>What is true of the efficiency of organizations for non-invidious work in
this respect is true also as regards the work of individuals proceeding on
the same motives; though it perhaps holds true with more qualification for
individuals than for organized enterprises. The habit of gauging merit by
the leisure-class canons of wasteful expenditure and unfamiliarity with
vulgar life, whether on the side of production or of consumption, is
necessarily strong in the individuals who aspire to do some work of public
utility. And if the individual should forget his station and turn his
efforts to vulgar effectiveness, the common sense of the community-the
sense of pecuniary decency—would presently reject his work and set
him right. An example of this is seen in the administration of bequests
made by public-spirited men for the single purpose (at least ostensibly)
of furthering the facility of human life in some particular respect. The
objects for which bequests of this class are most frequently made at
present are most frequently made at present are schools, libraries,
hospitals, and asylums for the infirm or unfortunate. The avowed purpose
of the donor in these cases is the amelioration of human life in the
particular respect which is named in the bequest; but it will be found an
invariable rule that in the execution of the work not a little of other
motives, frequency incompatible with the initial motive, is present and
determines the particular disposition eventually made of a good share of
the means which have been set apart by the bequest. Certain funds, for
instance, may have been set apart as a foundation for a foundling asylum
or a retreat for invalids. The diversion of expenditure to honorific waste
in such cases is not uncommon enough to cause surprise or even to raise a
smile. An appreciable share of the funds is spent in the construction of
an edifice faced with some aesthetically objectionable but expensive
stone, covered with grotesque and incongruous details, and designed, in
its battlemented walls and turrets and its massive portals and strategic
approaches, to suggest certain barbaric methods of warfare. The interior
of the structure shows the same pervasive guidance of the canons of
conspicuous waste and predatory exploit. The windows, for instance, to go
no farther into detail, are placed with a view to impress their pecuniary
excellence upon the chance beholder from the outside, rather than with a
view to effectiveness for their ostensible end in the convenience or
comfort of the beneficiaries within; and the detail of interior
arrangement is required to conform itself as best it may to this alien but
imperious requirement of pecuniary beauty.</p>
<p>In all this, of course, it is not to be presumed that the donor would have
found fault, or that he would have done otherwise if he had taken control
in person; it appears that in those cases where such a personal direction
is exercised—where the enterprise is conducted by direct expenditure
and superintendence instead of by bequest—the aims and methods of
management are not different in this respect. Nor would the beneficiaries,
or the outside observers whose ease or vanity are not immediately touched,
be pleased with a different disposition of the funds. It would suit no one
to have the enterprise conducted with a view directly to the most
economical and effective use of the means at hand for the initial,
material end of the foundation. All concerned, whether their interest is
immediate and self-regarding, or contemplative only, agree that some
considerable share of the expenditure should go to the higher or spiritual
needs derived from the habit of an invidious comparison in predatory
exploit and pecuniary waste. But this only goes to say that the canons of
emulative and pecuniary reputability so far pervade the common sense of
the community as to permit no escape or evasion, even in the case of an
enterprise which ostensibly proceeds entirely on the basis of a
non-invidious interest.</p>
<p>It may even be that the enterprise owes its honorific virtue, as a means
of enhancing the donor's good repute, to the imputed presence of this
non-invidious motive; but that does not hinder the invidious interest from
guiding the expenditure. The effectual presence of motives of an emulative
or invidious origin in non-emulative works of this kind might be shown at
length and with detail, in any one of the classes of enterprise spoken of
above. Where these honorific details occur, in such cases, they commonly
masquerade under designations that belong in the field of the aesthetic,
ethical or economic interest. These special motives, derived from the
standards and canons of the pecuniary culture, act surreptitiously to
divert effort of a non-invidious kind from effective service, without
disturbing the agent's sense of good intention or obtruding upon his
consciousness the substantial futility of his work. Their effect might be
traced through the entire range of that schedule of non-invidious,
meliorative enterprise that is so considerable a feature, and especially
so conspicuous a feature, in the overt scheme of life of the well-to-do.
But the theoretical bearing is perhaps clear enough and may require no
further illustration; especially as some detailed attention will be given
to one of these lines of enterprise—the establishments for the
higher learning—in another connection.</p>
<p>Under the circumstances of the sheltered situation in which the leisure
class is placed there seems, therefore, to be something of a reversion to
the range of non-invidious impulses that characterizes the ante-predatory
savage culture. The reversion comprises both the sense of workmanship and
the proclivity to indolence and good-fellowship. But in the modern scheme
of life canons of conduct based on pecuniary or invidious merit stand in
the way of a free exercise of these impulses; and the dominant presence of
these canons of conduct goes far to divert such efforts as are made on the
basis of the non-invidious interest to the service of that invidious
interest on which the pecuniary culture rests. The canons of pecuniary
decency are reducible for the present purpose to the principles of waste,
futility, and ferocity. The requirements of decency are imperiously
present in meliorative enterprise as in other lines of conduct, and
exercise a selective surveillance over the details of conduct and
management in any enterprise. By guiding and adapting the method in
detail, these canons of decency go far to make all non-invidious
aspiration or effort nugatory. The pervasive, impersonal, un-eager
principle of futility is at hand from day to day and works obstructively
to hinder the effectual expression of so much of the surviving
ante-predatory aptitudes as is to be classed under the instinct of
workmanship; but its presence does not preclude the transmission of those
aptitudes or the continued recurrence of an impulse to find expression for
them.</p>
<div style="break-after:column;"></div><br />