<h4>III. <i>Germany's Capacity to pay</i></h4>
<p>The forms in which Germany can discharge the sum which she has engaged
herself to pay are three in number—</p>
<p>1. Immediately transferable wealth in the form of gold, ships, and
foreign securities;</p>
<p>2. The value of property in ceded territory, or surrendered under the
Armistice;</p>
<p>3. Annual payments spread over a term of years, partly in cash and
partly in materials such as coal products, potash, and dyes.</p>
<p>There is excluded from the above the actual restitution of property
removed from territory occupied by the enemy, as, for example, Russian
gold, Belgian and French securities, cattle, machinery, and works of
art. In so far as the actual goods taken can be identified and restored,
they must clearly be returned to their rightful owners, and cannot be
brought into the general reparation pool. This is expressly provided for
in Article 238 of the Treaty.</p>
<p><br/></p>
<h4>1. <i>Immediately Transferable Wealth</i></h4>
<p>(<i>a</i>) <i>Gold</i>.—After deduction of the gold to be returned to Russia, the
official holding of gold as shown in the Reichsbank's return of the 30th
November, 1918, amounted to $577,089,500. This was a very much larger
amount than had appeared in the Reichsbank's return prior to the
war,<SPAN name="FNanchor_117_117" id="FNanchor_117_117" ></SPAN><SPAN href="#Footnote_117_117" class="fnanchor">[117]</SPAN> and was the result of the vigorous campaign carried on in
Germany during the war for the surrender to the Reichsbank not only of
gold coin but of gold ornaments of every kind. Private hoards doubtless
still exist, but, in view of the great efforts already made, it is
unlikely that either the German Government or the Allies will be able to
unearth them. The return can therefore be taken as probably representing
the maximum amount which the German Government are able to extract from
their people. In addition to gold there was in the Reichsbank a sum of
about $5,000,000 in silver. There must be, however, a further
substantial amount in circulation, for the holdings of the Reichsbank
were as high as $45,500,000 on the 31st December, 1917, and stood at
about $30,000,000 up to the latter part of October, 1918, when the
internal run began on currency of every kind.<SPAN name="FNanchor_118_118" id="FNanchor_118_118" ></SPAN><SPAN href="#Footnote_118_118" class="fnanchor">[118]</SPAN> We may, therefore,
take a total of (say) $625,000,000 for gold and silver together at the
date of the Armistice.</p>
<p>These reserves, however, are no longer intact. During the long period
which elapsed between the Armistice and the Peace it became necessary
for the Allies to facilitate the provisioning of Germany from abroad.
The political condition of Germany at that time and the serious menace
of Spartacism rendered this step necessary in the interests of the
Allies themselves if they desired the continuance in Germany of a stable
Government to treat with. The question of how such provisions were to be
paid for presented, however, the gravest difficulties. A series of
Conferences was held at Trèves, at Spa, at Brussels, and subsequently at
Château Villette and Versailles, between representatives of the Allies
and of Germany, with the object of finding some method of payment as
little injurious as possible to the future prospects of Reparation
payments. The German representatives maintained from the outset that the
financial exhaustion of their country was for the time being so complete
that a temporary loan from the Allies was the only possible expedient.
This the Allies could hardly admit at a time when they were preparing
demands for the immediate payment by Germany of immeasurably larger
sums. But, apart from this, the German claim could not be accepted as
strictly accurate so long as their gold was still untapped and their
remaining foreign securities unmarketed. In any case, it was out of the
question to suppose that in the spring of 1919 public opinion in the
Allied countries or in America would have allowed the grant of a
substantial loan to Germany. On the other hand, the Allies were
naturally reluctant to exhaust on the provisioning of Germany the gold
which seemed to afford one of the few obvious and certain sources for
Reparation. Much time was expended in the exploration of all possible
alternatives; but it was evident at last that, even if German exports
and saleable foreign securities had been available to a sufficient
value, they could not be liquidated in time, and that the financial
exhaustion of Germany was so complete that nothing whatever was
immediately available in substantial amounts except the gold in the
Reichsbank. Accordingly a sum exceeding $250,000,000 in all out of the
Reichsbank gold was transferred by Germany to the Allies (chiefly to the
United States, Great Britain, however, also receiving a substantial sum)
during the first six months of 1919 in payment for foodstuffs.</p>
<p>But this was not all. Although Germany agreed, under the first extension
of the Armistice, not to export gold without Allied permission, this
permission could not be always withheld. There were liabilities of the
Reichsbank accruing in the neighboring neutral countries, which could
not be met otherwise than in gold. The failure of the Reichsbank to meet
its liabilities would have caused a depreciation of the exchange so
injurious to Germany's credit as to react on the future prospects of
Reparation. In some cases, therefore, permission to export gold was
accorded to the Reichsbank by the Supreme Economic Council of the
Allies.</p>
<p>The net result of these various measures was to reduce the gold reserve
of the Reichsbank by more than half, the figures falling from
$575,000,000 to $275,000,000 in September, 1919.</p>
<p>It would be <i>possible</i> under the Treaty to take the whole of this latter
sum for Reparation purposes. It amounts, however, as it is, to less
than 4 per cent of the Reichsbank's Note Issue, and the psychological
effect of its total confiscation might be expected (having regard to the
very large volume of mark notes held abroad) to destroy the exchange
value of the mark almost entirely. A sum of $25,000,000, $50,000,000, or
even $100,000,000 might be taken for a special purpose. But we may
assume that the Reparation Commission will judge it imprudent, having
regard to the reaction on their future prospects of securing payment, to
ruin the German currency system altogether, more particularly because
the French and Belgian Governments, being holders of a very large volume
of mark notes formerly circulating in the occupied or ceded territory,
have a great interest in maintaining some exchange value for the mark,
quite apart from Reparation prospects.</p>
<p>It follows, therefore, that no sum worth speaking of can be expected in
the form of gold or silver towards the initial payment of $5,000,000,000
due by 1921.</p>
<p>(<i>b</i>) <i>Shipping</i>.—Germany has engaged, as we have seen above, to
surrender to the Allies virtually the whole of her merchant shipping. A
considerable part of it, indeed, was already in the hands of the Allies
prior to the conclusion of Peace, either by detention in their ports or
by the provisional transfer of tonnage under the Brussels Agreement in
connection with the supply of foodstuffs.<SPAN name="FNanchor_119_119" id="FNanchor_119_119" ></SPAN><SPAN href="#Footnote_119_119" class="fnanchor">[119]</SPAN> Estimating the tonnage of
German shipping to be taken over under the Treaty at 4,000,000 gross
tons, and the average value per ton at $150 per ton, the total money
value involved is $600,000,000.<SPAN name="FNanchor_120_120" id="FNanchor_120_120" ></SPAN><SPAN href="#Footnote_120_120" class="fnanchor">[120]</SPAN></p>
<p>(<i>c</i>) <i>Foreign Securities</i>.—Prior to the census of foreign securities
carried out by the German Government in September, 1916,<SPAN name="FNanchor_121_121" id="FNanchor_121_121" ></SPAN><SPAN href="#Footnote_121_121" class="fnanchor">[121]</SPAN> of which
the exact results have not been made public, no official return of such
investments was ever called for in Germany, and the various unofficial
estimates are confessedly based on insufficient data, such as the
admission of foreign securities to the German Stock Exchanges, the
receipts of the stamp duties, consular reports, etc. The principal
German estimates current before the war are given in the appended
footnote.<SPAN name="FNanchor_122_122" id="FNanchor_122_122" ></SPAN><SPAN href="#Footnote_122_122" class="fnanchor">[122]</SPAN> This shows a general consensus of opinion among German
authorities that their net foreign investments were upwards of
$6,250,000,000. I take this figure as the basis of my calculations,
although I believe it to be an exaggeration; $5,000,000,000 would
probably be a safer figure.</p>
<p>Deductions from this aggregate total have to be made under four heads.</p>
<p>(i.) Investments in Allied countries and in the United States, which
between them constitute a considerable part of the world, have been
sequestrated by Public Trustees, Custodians of Enemy Property, and
similar officials, and are not available for Reparation except in so far
as they show a surplus over various private claims. Under the scheme for
dealing with enemy debts outlined in Chapter IV., the first charge on
these assets is the private claims of Allied against German nationals.
It is unlikely, except in the United States, that there will be any
appreciable surplus for any other purpose.</p>
<p>(ii.) Germany's most important fields of foreign investment before the
war were not, like ours, oversea, but in Russia, Austria-Hungary,
Turkey, Roumania, and Bulgaria. A great part of these has now become
almost valueless, at any rate for the time being; especially those in
Russia and Austria-Hungary. If present market value is to be taken as
the test, none of these investments are now saleable above a nominal
figure. Unless the Allies are prepared to take over these securities
much above their nominal market valuation, and hold them for future
realization, there is no substantial source of funds for immediate
payment in the form of investments in these countries.</p>
<p>(iii.) While Germany was not in a position to realize her foreign
investments during the war to the degree that we were, she did so
nevertheless in the case of certain countries and to the extent that
she was able. Before the United States came into the war, she is
believed to have resold a large part of the pick of her investments in
American securities, although some current estimates of these sales (a
figure of $300,000,000 has been mentioned) are probably exaggerated. But
throughout the war and particularly in its later stages, when her
exchanges were weak and her credit in the neighboring neutral countries
was becoming very low, she was disposing of such securities as Holland,
Switzerland, and Scandinavia would buy or would accept as collateral. It
is reasonably certain that by June, 1919, her investments in these
countries had been reduced to a negligible figure and were far exceeded
by her liabilities in them. Germany has also sold certain overseas
securities, such as Argentine cedulas, for which a market could be
found.</p>
<p>(iv.) It is certain that since the Armistice there has been a great
flight abroad of the foreign securities still remaining in private
hands. This is exceedingly difficult to prevent. German foreign
investments are as a rule in the form of bearer securities and are not
registered. They are easily smuggled abroad across Germany's extensive
land frontiers, and for some months before the conclusion of peace it
was certain that their owners would not be allowed to retain them if the
Allied Governments could discover any method of getting hold of them.
These factors combined to stimulate human ingenuity, and the efforts
both of the Allied and of the German Governments to interfere
effectively with the outflow are believed to have been largely futile.</p>
<p>In face of all these considerations, it will be a miracle if much
remains for Reparation. The countries of the Allies and of the United
States, the countries of Germany's own allies, and the neutral countries
adjacent to Germany exhaust between them almost the whole of the
civilized world; and, as we have seen, we cannot expect much to be
available for Reparation from investments in any of these quarters.
Indeed there remain no countries of importance for investments except
those of South America.</p>
<p>To convert the significance of these deductions into figures involves
much guesswork. I give the reader the best personal estimate I can form
after pondering the matter in the light of the available figures and
other relevant data.</p>
<p>I put the deduction under (i.) at $1,500,000,000, of which $500,000,000
may be ultimately available after meeting private debts, etc.</p>
<p>As regards (ii.)—according to a census taken by the Austrian Ministry
of Finance on the 31st December, 1912, the nominal value of the
Austro-Hungarian securities held by Germans was $986,500,000. Germany's
pre-war investments in Russia outside Government securities have been
estimated at $475,000,000, which is much lower than would be expected,
and in 1906 Sartorius v. Waltershausen estimated her investments in
Russian Government securities at $750,000,000. This gives a total of
$1,225,000,000, which is to some extent borne out by the figure of
$1,000,000,000 given in 1911 by Dr. Ischchanian as a deliberately modest
estimate. A Roumanian estimate, published at the time of that country's
entry in the war, gave the value of Germany's investments in Roumania at
$20,000,000 to $22,000,000, of which $14,000,000 to $16,000,000 were in
Government securities. An association for the defense of French
interests in Turkey, as reported in the <i>Temps</i> (Sept. 8, 1919), has
estimated the total amount of German capital invested in Turkey at about
$295,000,000, of which, according to the latest Report of the Council of
Foreign Bondholders, $162,500,000 was held by German nationals in the
Turkish External Debt. No estimates are available to me of Germany's
investments in Bulgaria. Altogether I venture a deduction of
$2,500,000,000 in respect of this group of countries as a whole.</p>
<p>Resales and the pledging as collateral of securities during the war
under (iii.) I put at $500,000,000 to $750,000,000, comprising
practically all Germany's holding of Scandinavian, Dutch, and Swiss
securities, a part of her South American securities, and a substantial
proportion of her North American securities sold prior to the entry of
the United States into the war.</p>
<p>As to the proper deduction under (iv.) there are naturally no available
figures. For months past the European press has been full of sensational
stories of the expedients adopted. But if we put the value of securities
which have already left Germany or have been safely secreted within
Germany itself beyond discovery by the most inquisitorial and powerful
methods at $500,000,000, we are not likely to overstate it.</p>
<p>These various items lead, therefore, in all to a deduction of a round
figure of about $5,000,000,000, and leave us with an amount of
$1,250,000,000 theoretically still available.<SPAN name="FNanchor_123_126" id="FNanchor_123_126" ></SPAN><SPAN href="#Footnote_123_126" class="fnanchor">[123]</SPAN></p>
<p>To some readers this figure may seem low, but let them remember that it
purports to represent the remnant of <i>saleable</i> securities upon which
the German Government might be able to lay hands for public purposes. In
my own opinion it is much too high, and considering the problem by a
different method of attack I arrive at a lower figure. For leaving out
of account sequestered Allied securities and investments in Austria,
Russia, etc., what blocks of securities, specified by countries and
enterprises, can Germany possibly still have which could amount to as
much as $1,250,000,000? I cannot answer the question. She has some
Chinese Government securities which have not been sequestered, a few
Japanese perhaps, and a more substantial value of first-class South
American properties. But there are very few enterprises of this class
still in German hands, and even <i>their</i> value is measured by one or two
tens of millions, not by fifties or hundreds. He would be a rash man, in
my judgment, who joined a syndicate to pay $500,000,000 in cash for the
unsequestered remnant of Germany's overseas investments. If the
Reparation Commission is to realize even this lower figure, it is
probable that they will have to nurse, for some years, the assets which
they take over, not attempting their disposal at the present time.</p>
<p>We have, therefore, a figure of from $500,000,000 to $1,250,000,000 as
the maximum contribution from Germany's foreign securities.</p>
<p>Her immediately transferable wealth is composed, then, of—</p>
<p>(<i>a</i>) Gold and silver—say $300,000,000.</p>
<p>(<i>b</i>) Ships—$600,000,000.</p>
<p>(<i>c</i>) Foreign securities—$500,000,000 to $1,250,000,000.</p>
<p>Of the gold and silver, it is not, in fact, practicable to take any
substantial part without consequences to the German currency system
injurious to the interests of the Allies themselves. The contribution
from all these sources together which the Reparation Commission can hope
to secure by May, 1921, may be put, therefore, at from $1,250,000,000 to
$1,750,000,000 <i>as a maximum</i>.<SPAN name="FNanchor_124_127" id="FNanchor_124_127" ></SPAN><SPAN href="#Footnote_124_127" class="fnanchor">[124]</SPAN></p>
<p><br/></p>
<h4>2. <i>Property in ceded Territory or surrendered under the Armistice</i></h4>
<p>As the Treaty has been drafted Germany will not receive important
credits available towards meeting reparation in respect of her property
in ceded territory.</p>
<p><i>Private</i> property in most of the ceded territory is utilized towards
discharging private German debts to Allied nationals, and only the
surplus, if any, is available towards Reparation. The value of such
property in Poland and the other new States is payable direct to the
owners.</p>
<p><i>Government</i> property in Alsace-Lorraine, in territory ceded to Belgium,
and in Germany's former colonies transferred to a Mandatory, is to be
forfeited without credit given. Buildings, forests, and other State
property which belonged to the former Kingdom of Poland are also to be
surrendered without credit. There remain, therefore, Government
properties, other than the above, surrendered to Poland, Government
properties in Schleswig surrendered to Denmark,<SPAN name="FNanchor_125_128" id="FNanchor_125_128" ></SPAN><SPAN href="#Footnote_125_128" class="fnanchor">[125]</SPAN> the value of the
Saar coalfields, the value of certain river craft, etc., to be
surrendered under the Ports, Waterways, and Railways Chapter, and the
value of the German submarine cables transferred under Annex VII. of the
Reparation Chapter.</p>
<p>Whatever the Treaty may say, the Reparation Commission will not secure
any cash payments from Poland. I believe that the Saar coalfields have
been valued at from $75,000,000 to $100,000,000. A round figure of
$150,000,000 for all the above items, excluding any surplus available in
respect of private property, is probably a liberal estimate.</p>
<p>Then remains the value of material surrendered under the Armistice.
Article 250 provides that a credit shall be assessed by the Reparation
Commission for rolling-stock surrendered under the Armistice as well as
for certain other specified items, and generally for any material so
surrendered for which the Reparation Commission think that credit should
be given, "as having non-military value." The rolling-stock (150,000
wagons and 5,000 locomotives) is the only very valuable item. A round
figure of $250,000,000, for all the Armistice surrenders, is probably
again a liberal estimate.</p>
<p>We have, therefore, $400,000,000 to add in respect of this heading to
our figure of $1,250,000,000 to $1,750,000,000 under the previous
heading. This figure differs from the preceding in that it does not
represent cash capable of benefiting the financial situation of the
Allies, but is only a book credit between themselves or between them and
Germany.</p>
<p>The total of $1,650,000,000 to $2,150,000,000 now reached is not,
however, available for Reparation. The <i>first</i> charge upon it, under
Article 251 of the Treaty, is the cost of the Armies of Occupation both
during the Armistice and after the conclusion of Peace. The aggregate of
this figure up to May, 1921, cannot be calculated until the rate of
withdrawal is known which is to reduce the <i>monthly</i> cost from the
figure exceeding $100,000,000, which prevailed during the first part of
1919, to that of $5,000,000, which is to be the normal figure
eventually. I estimate, however, that this aggregate may be about
$1,000,000,000. This leaves us with from $500,000,000 to $1,000,000,000
still in hand.</p>
<p>Out of this, and out of exports of goods, and payments in kind under the
Treaty prior to May, 1921 (for which I have not as yet made any
allowance), the Allies have held out the hope that they will allow
Germany to receive back such sums for the purchase of necessary food and
raw materials as the former deem it essential for her to have. It is not
possible at the present time to form an accurate judgment either as to
the money-value of the goods which Germany will require to purchase from
abroad in order to re-establish her economic life, or as to the degree
of liberality with which the Allies will exercise their discretion. If
her stocks of raw materials and food were to be restored to anything
approaching their normal level by May, 1921, Germany would probably
require foreign purchasing power of from $500,000,000 to $1,000,000,000
at least, in addition to the value of her current exports. While this is
not likely to be permitted, I venture to assert as a matter beyond
reasonable dispute that the social and economic condition of Germany
cannot possibly permit a surplus of exports over imports during the
period prior to May, 1921, and that the value of any payments in kind
with which she may be able to furnish the Allies under the Treaty in the
form of coal, dyes, timber, or other materials will have to be returned
to her to enable her to pay for imports essential to her existence.<SPAN name="FNanchor_126_129" id="FNanchor_126_129" ></SPAN><SPAN href="#Footnote_126_129" class="fnanchor">[126]</SPAN></p>
<p>The Reparation Commission can, therefore, expect no addition from other
sources to the sum of from $500,000,000 to $1,000,000,000 with which we
have hypothetically credited it after the realization of Germany's
immediately transferable wealth, the calculation of the credits due to
Germany under the Treaty, and the discharge of the cost of the Armies of
Occupation. As Belgium has secured a private agreement with France, the
United States, and Great Britain, outside the Treaty, by which she is to
receive, towards satisfaction of her claims, the <i>first</i> $500,000,000
available for Reparation, the upshot of the whole matter is that Belgium
may <i>possibly</i> get her $500,000,000 by May, 1921, but none of the other
Allies are likely to secure by that date any contribution worth speaking
of. At any rate, it would be very imprudent for Finance Ministers to lay
their plans on any other hypothesis.</p>
<p><br/></p>
<h4>3. <i>Annual Payments spread over a Term of Years</i></h4>
<p>It is evident that Germany's pre-war capacity to pay an annual foreign
tribute has not been unaffected by the almost total loss of her
colonies, her overseas connections, her mercantile marine, and her
foreign properties, by the cession of ten per cent of her territory and
population, of one-third of her coal and of three-quarters of her iron
ore, by two million casualties amongst men in the prime of life, by the
starvation of her people for four years, by the burden of a vast war
debt, by the depreciation of her currency to less than one-seventh its
former value, by the disruption of her allies and their territories, by
Revolution at home and Bolshevism on her borders, and by all the
unmeasured ruin in strength and hope of four years of all-swallowing war
and final defeat.</p>
<p>All this, one would have supposed, is evident. Yet most estimates of a
great indemnity from Germany depend on the assumption that she is in a
position to conduct in the future a vastly greater trade than ever she
has had in the past.</p>
<p>For the purpose of arriving at a figure it is of no great consequence
whether payment takes the form of cash (or rather of foreign exchange)
or is partly effected in kind (coal, dyes, timber, etc.), as
contemplated by the Treaty. In any event, it is only by the export of
specific commodities that Germany can pay, and the method of turning the
value of these exports to account for Reparation purposes is,
comparatively, a matter of detail.</p>
<p>We shall lose ourselves in mere hypothesis unless we return in some
degree to first principles, and, whenever we can, to such statistics as
there are. It is certain that an annual payment can only be made by
Germany over a series of years by diminishing her imports and increasing
her exports, thus enlarging the balance in her favor which is available
for effecting payments abroad. Germany can pay in the long-run in goods,
and in goods only, whether these goods are furnished direct to the
Allies, or whether they are sold to neutrals and the neutral credits so
arising are then made over to the Allies. The most solid basis for
estimating the extent to which this process can be carried is to be
found, therefore, in an analysis of her trade returns before the war.
Only on the basis of such an analysis, supplemented by some general data
as to the aggregate wealth-producing capacity of the country, can a
rational guess be made as to the maximum degree to which the exports of
Germany could be brought to exceed her imports.</p>
<p>In the year 1913 Germany's imports amounted to $2,690,000,000, and her
exports to $2,525,000,000, exclusive of transit trade and bullion. That
is to say, imports exceeded exports by about $165,000,000. On the
average of the five years ending 1913, however, her imports exceeded her
exports by a substantially larger amount, namely, $370,000,000. It
follows, therefore, that more than the whole of Germany's pre-war
balance for new foreign investment was derived from the interest on her
existing foreign securities, and from the profits of her shipping,
foreign banking, etc. As her foreign properties and her mercantile
marine are now to be taken from her, and as her foreign banking and
other miscellaneous sources of revenue from abroad have been largely
destroyed, it appears that, on the pre-war basis of exports and imports,
Germany, so far from having a surplus wherewith to make a foreign
payment, would be not nearly self-supporting. Her first task, therefore,
must be to effect a readjustment of consumption and production to cover
this deficit. Any further economy she can effect in the use of imported
commodities, and any further stimulation of exports will then be
available for Reparation.</p>
<p>Two-thirds of Germany's import and export trade is enumerated under
separate headings in the following tables. The considerations applying
to the enumerated portions may be assumed to apply more or less to the
remaining one-third, which is composed of commodities of minor
importance individually.</p>
<p><br/></p>
<div class="ctr">
<table border="0" cellpadding="0" cellspacing="0" summary="">
<tr>
<td align="center" class="topbottom">German Exports, 1913</td>
<td align="center" class="all">Amount:<br/>Million<br/>Dollars</td>
<td align="center" class="topbottom"><span style="margin-right: 1em; margin-left: 1em;">Percentage of</span><br/>Total Exports</td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-right: 2em;">Iron goods (including tin plates, etc.)</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">330.65</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">13.2</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Machinery and parts (including<br/><span style="margin-left: 2em;">motor-cars)</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">187.75</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">7.5</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-right: 2em;">Coal, coke, and briquettes</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">176.70</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">7.0</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Woolen goods (including raw and<br/><span style="margin-left: 2em;">combed wool and clothing)</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">147.00</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">5.9</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Cotton goods (including raw cotton,<br/><span style="margin-left: 2em;">yarn, and thread)</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">140.75</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">5.6</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="all"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">982.85</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="topbottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">39.2</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Cereals, etc. (including rye, oats,<br/><span style="margin-left: 2em;">wheat, hops)</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">105.90</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">4.1</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Leather and leather goods</td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">77.35</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">3.0</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Sugar</td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">66.00</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">2.6</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Paper, etc.</td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">65.50</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">2.6</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Furs</td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">58.75</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">2.2</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Electrical goods (installations, ma-<br/><span style="margin-left: 2em;">chinery, lamps, cables)</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">54.40</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">2.2</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Silk goods</td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">50.50</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">2.0</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Dyes</td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">48.80</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">1.9</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Copper goods</td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">32.50</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">1.3</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Toys</td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">25.75</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">1.0</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Rubber and rubber goods</td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">21.35</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">0.9</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Books, maps, and music</td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">18.55</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">0.8</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Potash</td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">15.90</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">0.6</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Glass</td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">15.70</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">0.6</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Potassium chloride</td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">14.55</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">0.6</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Pianos, organs, and parts</td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">13.85</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">0.6</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Raw zinc</td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">13.70</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">0.5</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Porcelain</td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">12.65</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">0.5</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="all"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">711.70</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="topbottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">67.2</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Other goods, unenumerated</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">829.69</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">32.8</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td class="bottom"><span style="margin-left: 4em;">Total</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="all"><span style="margin-left: 1.5em; margin-right: 1.5em;">2,524.15</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="topbottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">100.0</span></td>
</tr>
</table></div>
<p><br/><br/></p>
<div class="ctr">
<table border="0" cellpadding="0" cellspacing="0" summary="">
<tr>
<td align="center" class="topbottom">German Imports, 1913</td>
<td align="center" class="all">Amount:<br/>Million<br/>Dollars</td>
<td align="center" class="topbottom"><span style="margin-right: 1em; margin-left: 1em;">Percentage of</span><br/>Total Exports</td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-right: 2em;">I. Raw materials:—</span></td>
<td class="leftright"> </td>
<td> </td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Cotton</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">151.75</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">5.6</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Hides and skins</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">124.30</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">4.6</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Wool</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">118.35</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">4.4</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Copper</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">83.75</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">3.1</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Coal</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">68.30</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">2.5</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Timber</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">58.00</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">2.2</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Iron ore</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">56.75</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">2.1</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Furs</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">46.75</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">1.7</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Flax and flaxseed</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">46.65</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">1.7</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Saltpetre</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">42.75</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">1.6</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Silk</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">39.50</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">1.5</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Rubber</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">36.50</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">1.4</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Jute</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">23.50</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">0.9</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Petroleum</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">17.45</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">0.7</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Tin</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">14.55</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">0.5</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Phosphorus chalk</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">11.60</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">0.4</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Lubricating oil</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">11.45</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">0.4</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="all"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">951.90</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="topbottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">35.3</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-right: 2em;">II. Food, tobacco, etc.:—</span></td>
<td class="leftright"> </td>
<td> </td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Cereals, etc. (wheat, barley,</span><br/>
<span style="margin-left: 4em; margin-right: 2em;">bran, rice, maize, oats, rye,</span><br/>
<span style="margin-left: 4em;">clover)</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">327.55</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">12.2</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Oil seeds and cake, etc. (in-</span><br/>
<span style="margin-left: 4em;">cluding palm kernels, copra,</span><br/>
<span style="margin-left: 4em;">cocoa beans)</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">102.65</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">3.8</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Cattle, lamb fat, bladders</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">73.10</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">2.8</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Coffee</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">54.75</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">2.0</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Eggs</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">48.50</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">1.8</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Tobacco</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">33.50</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">1.2</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Butter</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">29.65</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">1.1</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Horses</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">29.05</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">1.1</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Fruit</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">18.25</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">0.7</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Fish</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">14.95</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">0.6</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Poultry</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">14.00</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">0.6</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Wine</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">13.35</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">0.5</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="all"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">759.30</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="topbottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">28.3</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-right: 2em;">III. Manufactures:—</span></td>
<td class="leftright"> </td>
<td> </td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Cotton yarn and thread and</span><br/>
<span style="margin-left: 4em;">cotton goods</span><br/></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">47.05</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">1.8</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Woolen yarn and woolen</span><br/>
<span style="margin-left: 4em;">goods</span><br/></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">37.85</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">1.4</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em;">Machinery</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">20.10</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">0.7</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="all"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">105.00</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="topbottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">3.9</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>IV. Unenumerated</td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="leftright"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em;">876.40</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">32.5</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td class="bottom"><span style="margin-left: 4em;">Total</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="all"><span style="margin-right: 1.5em; margin-left: 1.5em;">2,692.60</span></td>
<td align="right" valign="bottom" class="topbottom"><span style="margin-right: 2.5em;">100.0</span></td>
</tr>
</table></div>
<p><br/></p>
<p>These tables show that the most important exports consisted of:—</p>
<ol>
<li>Iron Goods, including tin plates (13.2 per cent),</li>
<li>Machinery, etc. (7.5 per cent),</li>
<li>Coal, coke, and briquettes (7 per cent),</li>
<li>Woolen goods, including raw and combed wool (5.9 per cent), and</li>
<li>Cotton goods, including cotton yarn and thread and raw cotton (5.6 per cent),</li>
</ol>
<p>these five classes between them accounting for 39.2 per cent. of the
total exports. It will be observed that all these goods are of a kind in
which before the war competition between Germany and the United Kingdom
was very severe. If, therefore, the volume of such exports to overseas
or European destinations is very largely increased the effect upon
British export trade must be correspondingly serious. As regards two of
the categories, namely, cotton and woolen goods, the increase of an
export trade is dependent upon an increase of the import of the raw
material, since Germany produces no cotton and practically no wool.
These trades are therefore incapable of expansion unless Germany is
given facilities for securing these raw materials (which can only be at
the expense of the Allies) in excess of the pre-war standard of
consumption, and even then the effective increase is not the gross value
of the exports, but only the difference between the value of the
manufactured exports and of the imported raw material. As regards the
other three categories, namely, machinery, iron goods, and coal,
Germany's capacity to increase her exports will have been taken from her
by the cessions of territory in Poland, Upper Silesia, and
Alsace-Lorraine. As has been pointed out already, these districts
accounted for nearly one-third of Germany's production of coal. But they
also supplied no less than three-quarters of her iron-ore production, 38
per cent of her blast furnaces, and 9.5 per cent of her iron and steel
foundries. Unless, therefore, Alsace-Lorraine and Upper Silesia send
their iron ore to Germany proper, to be worked up, which will involve an
increase in the imports for which she will have to find payment, so far
from any increase in export trade being possible, a decrease is
inevitable.<SPAN name="FNanchor_127_130" id="FNanchor_127_130" ></SPAN><SPAN href="#Footnote_127_130" class="fnanchor">[127]</SPAN></p>
<p>Next on the list come cereals, leather goods, sugar, paper, furs,
electrical goods, silk goods, and dyes. Cereals are not a net export and
are far more than balanced by imports of the same commodities. As
regards sugar, nearly 90 per cent of Germany's pre-war exports came to
the United Kingdom.<SPAN name="FNanchor_128_131" id="FNanchor_128_131" ></SPAN><SPAN href="#Footnote_128_131" class="fnanchor">[128]</SPAN> An increase in this trade might be stimulated
by a grant of a preference in this country to German sugar or by an
arrangement by which sugar was taken in part payment for the indemnity
on the same lines as has been proposed for coal, dyes, etc. Paper
exports also might be capable of some increase. Leather goods, furs, and
silks depend upon corresponding imports on the other side of the
account. Silk goods are largely in competition with the trade of France
and Italy. The remaining items are individually very small. I have heard
it suggested that the indemnity might be paid to a great extent in
potash and the like. But potash before the war represented 0.6 per cent
of Germany's export trade, and about $15,000,000 in aggregate value.
Besides, France, having secured a potash field in the territory which
has been restored to her, will not welcome a great stimulation of the
German exports of this material.</p>
<p>An examination of the import list shows that 63.6 per cent are raw
materials and food. The chief items of the former class, namely, cotton,
wool, copper, hides, iron-ore, furs, silk, rubber, and tin, could not be
much reduced without reacting on the export trade, and might have to be
increased if the export trade was to be increased. Imports of food,
namely, wheat, barley, coffee, eggs, rice, maize, and the like, present
a different problem. It is unlikely that, apart from certain comforts,
the consumption of food by the German laboring classes before the war
was in excess of what was required for maximum efficiency; indeed, it
probably fell short of that amount. Any substantial decrease in the
imports of food would therefore react on the efficiency of the
industrial population, and consequently on the volume of surplus exports
which they could be forced to produce. It is hardly possible to insist
on a greatly increased productivity of German industry if the workmen
are to be underfed. But this may not be equally true of barley, coffee,
eggs, and tobacco. If it were possible to enforce a régime in which for
the future no German drank beer or coffee, or smoked any tobacco, a
substantial saving could be effected. Otherwise there seems little room
for any significant reduction.</p>
<p>The following analysis of German exports and imports, according to
destination and origin, is also relevant. From this it appears that of
Germany's exports in 1913, 18 per cent went to the British Empire, 17
per cent to France, Italy, and Belgium, 10 per cent to Russia and
Roumania, and 7 per cent to the United States; that is to say, more than
half of the exports found their market in the countries of the Entente
nations. Of the balance, 12 per cent went to Austria-Hungary, Turkey,
and Bulgaria, and 35 per cent elsewhere. Unless, therefore, the present
Allies are prepared to encourage the importation of German products, a
substantial increase in total volume can only be effected by the
wholesale swamping of neutral markets.</p>
<p><br/><br/></p>
<div class="ctr">
<table border="0" cellpadding="0" cellspacing="0" summary="">
<tr>
<td colspan="10" align="center"><span class="smcap">German Trade (1913) According to Destination and Origin</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td class="topbottom"> </td>
<td colspan="5" align="center" class="all">Destination of<br/>Germany's Exports</td>
<td colspan="4" align="center" class="topbottom">Origin of<br/>Germany's Imports</td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td> </td>
<td class="left"> </td>
<td align="center">Million<br/>Dollars</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="center">Per cent</td>
<td class="right"> </td>
<td> </td>
<td align="center">Million<br/>Dollars</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="center">Per cent</td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Great Britain</td>
<td class="left"> </td>
<td align="right">359.65</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">14.2</span></td>
<td class="right"> </td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right">219.00</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">8.1</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>India</td>
<td class="left"> </td>
<td align="right">37.65</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">1.5</span></td>
<td class="right"> </td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right">135.20</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">5.0</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Egypt</td>
<td class="left"> </td>
<td align="right">10.85</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">0.4</span></td>
<td class="right"> </td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right">29.60</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">1.1</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Canada</td>
<td class="left"> </td>
<td align="right">15.10</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">0.6</span></td>
<td class="right"> </td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right">16.00</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">0.6</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Australia</td>
<td class="left"> </td>
<td align="right">22.10</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">0.9</span></td>
<td class="right"> </td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right">74.00</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">2.8</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>South Africa</td>
<td class="left"> </td>
<td align="right">11.70</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">0.5</span></td>
<td class="right"> </td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right">17.40</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">0.6</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td><span style="margin-left: 2em; margin-right: 2em;">Total: British Empire</span></td>
<td class="left"> </td>
<td align="right" class="top">456.95</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right" class="top"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">18.1</span></td>
<td class="right"> </td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right" class="top">491.20</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right" class="top"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">18.2</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td> </td>
<td class="left"> </td>
<td> </td>
<td> </td>
<td> </td>
<td class="right"> </td>
<td> </td>
<td> </td>
<td> </td>
<td> </td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>France</td>
<td class="left"> </td>
<td align="right">197.45</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">7.8</span></td>
<td class="right"> </td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right">146.65</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">5.4</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Belgium</td>
<td class="left"> </td>
<td align="right">137.75</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">5.5</span></td>
<td class="right"> </td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right">86.15</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">3.2</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Italy</td>
<td class="left"> </td>
<td align="right">98.35</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">3.9</span></td>
<td class="right"> </td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right">79.40</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">3.0</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>U. S. A.</td>
<td class="left"> </td>
<td align="right">178.30</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">7.1</span></td>
<td class="right"> </td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right">427.80</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">15.9</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Russia</td>
<td class="left"> </td>
<td align="right">220.00</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">8.7</span></td>
<td class="right"> </td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right">356.15</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">13.2</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Roumania</td>
<td class="left"> </td>
<td align="right">35.00</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">1.4</span></td>
<td class="right"> </td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right">19.95</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">0.7</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Austria-Hungary</td>
<td class="left"> </td>
<td align="right">276.20</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">10.9</span></td>
<td class="right"> </td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right">206.80</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">7.7</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Turkey</td>
<td class="left"> </td>
<td align="right">24.60</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">1.0</span></td>
<td class="right"> </td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right">18.40</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">0.7</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Bulgaria</td>
<td class="left"> </td>
<td align="right">7.55</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">0.3</span></td>
<td class="right"> </td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right">2.00</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">...</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td>Other countries</td>
<td class="left"> </td>
<td align="right">800.20</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">35.3</span></td>
<td class="right"> </td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right">858.70</td>
<td> </td>
<td align="right"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">32.0</span></td>
</tr>
<tr>
<td class="bottom"> </td>
<td class="leftbottom"> </td>
<td align="right" class="topbottom">2,522.35</td>
<td class="bottom"> </td>
<td align="right" class="topbottom"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">100.0</span></td>
<td class="rightbottom"> </td>
<td class="bottom"> </td>
<td align="right" class="topbottom">2,692.60</td>
<td class="bottom"> </td>
<td align="right" class="topbottom"><span style="margin-right: 0.5em;">100.0</span></td>
</tr>
</table></div>
<p><br/><br/></p>
<p>The above analysis affords some indication of the possible magnitude of
the maximum modification of Germany's export balance under the
conditions which will prevail after the Peace. On the assumptions (1)
that we do not specially favor Germany over ourselves in supplies of
such raw materials as cotton and wool (the world's supply of which is
limited), (2) that France, having secured the iron-ore deposits, makes a
serious attempt to secure the blast-furnaces and the steel trade also,
(3) that Germany is not encouraged and assisted to undercut the iron and
other trades of the Allies in overseas market, and (4) that a
substantial preference is not given to German goods in the British
Empire, it is evident by examination of the specific items that not much
is practicable.</p>
<p>Let us run over the chief items again: (1) Iron goods. In view of
Germany's loss of resources, an increased net export seems impossible
and a large decrease probable. (2) Machinery. Some increase is possible.
(3) Coal and coke. The value of Germany's net export before the war was
$110,000,000; the Allies have agreed that for the time being 20,000,000
tons is the maximum possible export with a problematic (and in fact)
impossible increase to 40,000,000 tons at some future time; even on the
basis of 20,000,000 tons we have virtually no increase of value,
measured in pre-war prices;<SPAN name="FNanchor_129_132" id="FNanchor_129_132" ></SPAN><SPAN href="#Footnote_129_132" class="fnanchor">[129]</SPAN> whilst, if this amount is exacted,
there must be a decrease of far greater value in the export of
manufactured articles requiring coal for their production. (4) Woolen
goods. An increase is impossible without the raw wool, and, having
regard to the other claims on supplies of raw wool, a decrease is
likely. (5) Cotton goods. The same considerations apply as to wool. (6)
Cereals. There never was and never can be a net export. (7) Leather
goods. The same considerations apply as to wool.</p>
<p>We have now covered nearly half of Germany's pre-war exports, and there
is no other commodity which formerly represented as much as 3 per cent
of her exports. In what commodity is she to pay? Dyes?—their total
value in 1913 was $50,000,000. Toys? Potash?—1913 exports were worth
$15,000,000. And even if the commodities could be specified, in what
markets are they to be sold?—remembering that we have in mind goods to
the value not of tens of millions annually, but of hundreds of millions.</p>
<p>On the side of imports, rather more is possible. By lowering the
standard of life, an appreciable reduction of expenditure on imported
commodities may be possible. But, as we have already seen, many large
items are incapable of reduction without reacting on the volume of
exports.</p>
<p>Let us put our guess as high as we can without being foolish, and
suppose that after a time Germany will be able, in spite of the
reduction of her resources, her facilities, her markets, and her
productive power, to increase her exports and diminish her imports so as
to improve her trade balance altogether by $500,000,000 annually,
measured in pre-war prices. This adjustment is first required to
liquidate the adverse trade balance, which in the five years before the
war averaged $370,000,000; but we will assume that after allowing for
this, she is left with a favorable trade balance of $250,000,000 a year.
Doubling this to allow for the rise in pre-war prices, we have a figure
of $500,000,000. Having regard to the political, social, and human
factors, as well as to the purely economic, I doubt if Germany could be
made to pay this sum annually over a period of 30 years; but it would
not be foolish to assert or to hope that she could.</p>
<p>Such a figure, allowing 5 per cent for interest, and 1 per cent for
repayment of capital, represents a capital sum having a present value of
about $8,500,000,000.<SPAN name="FNanchor_130_133" id="FNanchor_130_133" ></SPAN><SPAN href="#Footnote_130_133" class="fnanchor">[130]</SPAN></p>
<p>I reach, therefore, the final conclusion that, including all methods of
payment—immediately transferable wealth, ceded property, and an annual
tribute—$10,000,000,000 is a safe maximum figure of Germany's capacity
to pay. In all the actual circumstances, I do not believe that she can
pay as much. Let those who consider this a very low figure, bear in mind
the following remarkable comparison. The wealth of France in 1871 was
estimated at a little less than half that of Germany in 1913. Apart from
changes in the value of money, an indemnity from Germany of
$2,500,000,000 would, therefore, be about comparable to the sum paid by
France in 1871; and as the real burden of an indemnity increases more
than in proportion to its amount, the payment of $10,000,000,000 by
Germany would have far severer consequences than the $1,000,000,000 paid
by France in 1871.</p>
<p>There is only one head under which I see a possibility of adding to the
figure reached on the line of argument adopted above; that is, if German
labor is actually transported to the devastated areas and there engaged
in the work of reconstruction. I have heard that a limited scheme of
this kind is actually in view. The additional contribution thus
obtainable depends on the number of laborers which the German Government
could contrive to maintain in this way and also on the number which,
over a period of years, the Belgian and French inhabitants would
tolerate in their midst. In any case, it would seem very difficult to
employ on the actual work of reconstruction, even over a number of
years, imported labor having a net present value exceeding (say)
$1,250,000,000; and even this would not prove in practice a net addition
to the annual contributions obtainable in other ways.</p>
<p>A capacity of $40,000,000,000 or even of $25,000,000,000 is, therefore,
not within the limits of reasonable possibility. It is for those who
believe that Germany can make an annual payment amounting to hundreds of
millions sterling to say <i>in what specific commodities</i> they intend this
payment to be made and <i>in what markets</i> the goods are to be sold. Until
they proceed to some degree of detail, and are able to produce some
tangible argument in favor of their conclusions, they do not deserve to
be believed.<SPAN name="FNanchor_131_134" id="FNanchor_131_134" ></SPAN><SPAN href="#Footnote_131_134" class="fnanchor">[131]</SPAN></p>
<p>I make three provisos only, none of which affect the force of my
argument for immediate practical purposes.</p>
<p><i>First</i>: if the Allies were to "nurse" the trade and industry of Germany
for a period of five or ten years, supplying her with large loans, and
with ample shipping, food, and raw materials during that period,
building up markets for her, and deliberately applying all their
resources and goodwill to making her the greatest industrial nation in
Europe, if not in the world, a substantially larger sum could probably
be extracted thereafter; for Germany is capable of very great
productivity.</p>
<p><i>Second</i>: whilst I estimate in terms of money, I assume that there is no
revolutionary change in the purchasing power of our unit of value. If
the value of gold were to sink to a half or a tenth of its present
value, the real burden of a payment fixed in terms of gold would be
reduced proportionately. If a sovereign comes to be worth what a
shilling is worth now, then, of course, Germany can pay a larger sum
than I have named, measured in gold sovereigns.</p>
<p><i>Third</i>: I assume that there is no revolutionary change in the yield of
Nature and material to man's labor. It is not <i>impossible</i> that the
progress of science should bring within our reach methods and devices by
which the whole standard of life would be raised immeasurably, and a
given volume of products would represent but a portion of the human
effort which it represents now. In this case all standards of "capacity"
would be changed everywhere. But the fact that all things are <i>possible</i>
is no excuse for talking foolishly.</p>
<p>It is true that in 1870 no man could have predicted Germany's capacity
in 1910. We cannot expect to legislate for a generation or more. The
secular changes in man's economic condition and the liability of human
forecast to error are as likely to lead to mistake in one direction as
in another. We cannot as reasonable men do better than base our policy
on the evidence we have and adapt it to the five or ten years over which
we may suppose ourselves to have some measure of prevision; and we are
not at fault if we leave on one side the extreme chances of human
existence and of revolutionary changes in the order of Nature or of
man's relations to her. The fact that we have no adequate knowledge of
Germany's capacity to pay over a long period of years is no
justification (as I have heard some people claim that, it is) for the
statement that she can pay $50,000,000,000.</p>
<p>Why has the world been so credulous of the unveracities of politicians?
If an explanation is needed, I attribute this particular credulity to
the following influences in part.</p>
<p>In the first place, the vast expenditures of the war, the inflation of
prices, and the depreciation of currency, leading up to a complete
instability of the unit of value, have made us lose all sense of number
and magnitude in matters of finance. What we believed to be the limits
of possibility have been so enormously exceeded, and those who founded
their expectations on the past have been so often wrong, that the man in
the street is now prepared to believe anything which is told him with
some show of authority, and the larger the figure the more readily he
swallows it.</p>
<p>But those who look into the matter more deeply are sometimes misled by a
fallacy, much more plausible to reasonableness. Such a one might base
his conclusions on Germany's total surplus of annual productivity as
distinct from her export surplus. Helfferich's estimate of Germany's
annual increment of wealth in 1913 was $2,000,000,000 to $2,125,000,000
(exclusive of increased money value of existing land and property).
Before the war, Germany spent between $250,000,000 and $500,000,000 on
armaments, with which she can now dispense. Why, therefore, should she
not pay over to the Allies an annual sum of $2,500,000,000? This puts
the crude argument in its strongest and most plausible form.</p>
<p>But there are two errors in it. First of all, Germany's annual savings,
after what she has suffered in the war and by the Peace, will fall far
short of what they were before, and, if they are taken from her year by
year in future, they cannot again reach their previous level. The loss
of Alsace-Lorraine, Poland, and Upper Silesia could not be assessed in
terms of surplus productivity at less than $250,000,000 annually.
Germany is supposed to have profited about $500,000,000 per annum from
her ships, her foreign investments, and her foreign banking and
connections, all of which have now been taken from her. Her saving on
armaments is far more than balanced by her annual charge for pensions
now estimated at $1,250,000,000,<SPAN name="FNanchor_132_135" id="FNanchor_132_135" ></SPAN><SPAN href="#Footnote_132_135" class="fnanchor">[132]</SPAN> which represents a real loss of
productive capacity. And even if we put on one side the burden of the
internal debt, which amounts to 24 milliards of marks, as being a
question of internal distribution rather than of productivity, we must
still allow for the foreign debt incurred by Germany during the war, the
exhaustion of her stock of raw materials, the depletion of her
live-stock, the impaired productivity of her soil from lack of manures
and of labor, and the diminution in her wealth from the failure to keep
up many repairs and renewals over a period of nearly five years. Germany
is not as rich as she was before the war, and the diminution in her
future savings for these reasons, quite apart from the factors
previously allowed for, could hardly be put at less than ten per cent,
that is $200,000,000 annually.</p>
<p>These factors have already reduced Germany's annual surplus to less than
the $500,000,000 at which we arrived on other grounds as the maximum of
her annual payments. But even if the rejoinder be made, that we have not
yet allowed for the lowering of the standard of life and comfort in
Germany which may reasonably be imposed on a defeated enemy,<SPAN name="FNanchor_133_136" id="FNanchor_133_136" ></SPAN><SPAN href="#Footnote_133_136" class="fnanchor">[133]</SPAN> there
is still a fundamental fallacy in the method of calculation. An annual
surplus available for home investment can only be converted into a
surplus available for export abroad by a radical change in the kind of
work performed. Labor, while it may be available and efficient for
domestic services in Germany, may yet be able to find no outlet in
foreign trade. We are back on the same question which faced us in our
examination of the export trade—in <i>what</i> export trade is German labor
going to find a greatly increased outlet? Labor can only he diverted
into new channels with loss of efficiency, and a large expenditure of
capital. The annual surplus which German labor can produce for capital
improvements at home is no measure, either theoretically or practically,
of the annual tribute which she can pay abroad.</p>
<div style="break-after:column;"></div><br />